English Deutsch Français Italiano Español Português 繁體中文 Bahasa Indonesia Tiếng Việt ภาษาไทย
All categories

Please please please help some1 its for college, i dont no where to look.

2006-10-11 05:10:14 · 28 answers · asked by Loving and loved 2 in Education & Reference Homework Help

28 answers

Well if you want to copy and paste this.. heres what I have.
What I have copied for you below will at least give you an idea of where to start and how to find what is needed, if not give you what you want exactly.

Welfare Policy:
The primary factors that attribute to the stark differences in welfare policy among the United States of America and various countries of the European Union, specifically the United Kingdom



by M. Katharine Brunson



Abstract

In this comparative research paper, general American and European welfare policy is analyzed. It is ironic that the United States can crush the cruelest of regimes, yet cannot alleviate the social miseries within her own land, which happens to be the world’s richest country. The United Kingdom on the other hand, offers a much more comprehensive and acceptable welfare system for her citizens. This is consistent with the social service trends in the rest of Europe. This paper discusses the primary reasons for the differences in welfare policy between the two most powerful democratic states in the world, the United States of America and the United Kingdom.



Introduction

Political views can roughly be divided into “leftist” and “rightist” standpoints. The left wing is typically more liberal in thought and is a strong supporter of institutional welfare. Institutional welfare provides for every citizen, regardless of economic status. Furthermore, leftist policies support public provision through high government intervention and collectivist ideas. The United Kingdom clearly outlines these points in her social policies and welfare program. In contrast, the right wing is conservative and against most forms of public welfare. The only acceptable form of public provision is residual welfare, which is welfare implemented only as a safety net for those who can not manage, such as the low-income households or disabled peoples. The right wing tends to be more individualist in social positions and favors small government with little intervention. The United States is an example of the “right” political ideology. This fundamental difference clearly separates the political foundation of the United States and United Kingdom, especially in reference to welfare policies.

British Welfare

1929 was a pivotal year across the globe. When the United States stock market crashed, ripples were felt across Europe. As hardship and instability walked hand-in-hand into the 1930s, they met increasing unemployment and poverty. As president of the United States, Franklin D. Roosevelt took action by implementing a new economic strategy in the New Deal. This model was the “optimistic activism, experimentation, and interventionist reforms” that the country so desperately needed at the time (Yergin et al., 1998, page 22). While the USA committed herself to social justice and firmly held the belief of government responsibility towards its citizens, the USSR praised socialism and evolved communism.

The United Kingdom saw the action other global governments were taking, and decided to follow the lead. With the onset of World War II, the British government seized the national economy and used the opportunity to turn it into “a common cause rather than an area of class conflict” (Yergin et al., 1998, page 23). War proved to transform the decision makers of the government and thus, Britain built upon her wartime experiences and further developed her political institutions. The Labor party published the Beveridge Report (1942), the bestselling “report (that) set out social programs to slay the ‘five giants’: Want, Disease, Ignorance, Squalor, and Idleness” (Yergin et al., 1998, page 23). As a result, the Labor government quickly “established free medical care under a newly constituted National Health Service, created new systems of pensions, promoted better education and housing, and sought to deliver on the explicit commitment to ‘full employment’” (Yergin et al., 1998, page 25. In 1945, the United Kingdom gave birth to the first modern welfare state.

With both the Conservative Party and Labor Party fully backing the ideals of the Beveridge Report, British citizens saw many new opportunities. By 1948, the welfare state evolved into “social security, health, housing, education, and personal social services” within the government (Social Policy in the UK). The welfare state was not established to rid the country of poverty, but rather to make social services as available as public services. This belief wanted programs, such as health care and employment benefits, to be as accessible and well developed as paved roads and public transportation. This ideology would spark debate in future years.

Over the past fifty years, the British welfare state developed drastically through two major reforms; the first in the 1960s and the second in the 1980s. The first reform focused on central government. It was necessary to make economic planning and spending more efficient. Thus, efforts were made to give public expenditure responsibilities to the national Treasury. The result was a system that could distribute resources from the Treasury to respective departments and onto various specialty services in an orderly fashion.

The second major reform focused on renovating the administration of welfare, specifically health care and social care. This had three main elements to it. First, reorganization forced the administration to divide into agencies with the hope of encouraging individual assessment. A perfect example of this is the advancement of the National Health Service (NHS) trusts. Secondly, agencies implemented management positions to effectively run as businesses. Social services commonly used this tactic to promote efficiency and productivity. Lastly, the services changed to operate as economic markets. Thus, a separation of purchase and provision would exist with the encouragement of competition.

For the past twenty years, continued reform in the UK has changed welfare’s cash benefits, health care, education, and public housing. The most widely utilized aspect of welfare benefits used today are cash benefits, which total 10 percent of the country’s Gross Domestic Product (GDP) (Glazer, 2003, page 111). Cash benefits consist of national insurance, means-tested programs, and non-contributory benefits. Secondly, health care is organized by the NHS, which is financed by taxes. Health care in Britain is universal and virtually free to its people, making it very popular. But, since priority is given to the most severe cases, there are long lines that can last years. Additionally, education is free to children ages five to sixteen. Thus, higher education is a direct reflection of class bias and social hierarchy. In terms of housing, owner-occupation is the most popular option because it is based on a taxation grant system. These services help to effectively alleviate social miseries for Britons.

The United Kingdom, as a welfare state, is identified, in practice, with the institutional model of welfare. A defining characteristic of institutional welfare is the fact that welfare is not just for the needy, but rather, it is available to everyone. Thus, social stigma that would commonly be associated with welfare is dissolved. This model’s foundation claims “social protection and the provision of welfare services on the basis of right” (Social Policy in the UK). The UK deviates from this model slightly. Although coverage is extensive, benefits and services are delivered at depleting degrees. Furthermore, citizens find social protection to be erratic and services to be harshly allocated.

Two of the greatest challenges facing the welfare state in the UK is the aging population as well as increasing levels of unemployment. A growing elderly population requires more time, resources, assistance, and services that a smaller middle-aged population cannot fully provide. Secondly, when the government saw that 13 percent of the population was unemployed in the 1980s, immediate action was necessary (Faher, 2000). Job training was the answer to the ridiculously high unemployment rates. By the 1990s, unemployment fell to six percent (Faher, 2000). Comparatively, in a 2004 estimate, it was reported that roughly 5.5 percent of the American population was unemployed (Faher, 2000). Continued efforts to further decrease the unemployment percentages in both countries are currently in place.

American Welfare

The United States has been branded the land of opportunity. But, opportunity does not denote equality. Nathan Glazer, professor of sociology and education emeritus at Harvard University, argues that the United States is the most unequal of economically developed countries. Compiled statistics show that the United States redistributes significantly less transfers and other social benefits in comparison to European countries. These decreased redistributions are a result of higher before-tax income inequality and a skewed income distribution in the United States.

The United States, although conservative in political ideology, is often identified with liberal policies in welfare, as the country clearly represents individualism and laissez-faire methods. The two reforms in welfare policy were in the 1930s and 1960s. In the 1930s, President Franklin D. Roosevelt’s administration offered a variety of federal provisions that paved the way for today’s social security programs. Health care benefits were the main product out of the “War on Poverty” in the 1960s.

The United States government is severely lacking a comprehensive and productive welfare system. What is ironic is alternative governmental programs are better than what the welfare system gives low-income and disabled Americans. For example, in 1999, Alabama’s welfare benefits for a family of three totaled $164 per month, whereas food-stamp allotment for the same family totaled $329 per month (Glazer, 2003, page 114). It is financially more reasonable to leave welfare and take the food-stamps. Currently, food-stamps and government housing are better options for the American poor than basic welfare’s monthly payments. So, what incentive is there for tax payers to support welfare, if the government provides more reasonable options? The problem is there is no incentive, so it should be of no shock that a deflated welfare state is in place.

The United States’ redistribution plan to society’s worse-off is much less efficient than that in European countries. For example, in 1999, social benefits and transfers totaled 11 percent of America’s GDP (Glazer, 2003, page 111). Comparatively, social benefits and transfers totaled 18 percent in countries of the European Union, with a range from 20 percent in France and Germany to 16 percent in the United Kingdom (Glazer, 2003, page 111). Additionally, family benefits, unemployment, and labor market programs amount to only one percent of American GDP in contrast to the five percent in the European Union (Glazer, 2003, page 111). These are not the only areas that the United States is lacking, because the United States also falls behind Europe in old-age, disability, and survivors benefits as well. Clearly, better services for citizens, not just the needy, are in place in Europe.

Perhaps it is the United States’ stringent classification of the “haves” and the “have-nots,” or the working versus the unemployed, which stunt the growth of a flourishing welfare system. Americans might be apathetic towards the poor, but there is definitely a strong social stigma attached with unemployment, and even welfare assistance in general. Not only are unemployment benefits much lower in the United States than in Europe, but the legal minimum wage is significantly less as well. Just how miserable is it to be unemployed in America? The least supportive European unemployment plan exists in the United Kingdom, and even there unemployed Britons receive benefits for four years. In contrast, unemployed Americans are only guaranteed benefits for six months. Furthermore, in the 1990s, the legal American minimum wage was 39 percent of the average wage, whereas it was 53 percent of the average wage in the European Union (Glazer, 2003, page 112). Even for those who are employed in America, it is not legally required for employers to offer paid vacations. France and Sweden grant paid vacations of five weeks per year while the European average rests at four weeks per year. Again, Europe offers better compensation in the form of a welfare state.

Welfare Comparison

As far as the actual welfare system, most of Europe and the United States hold opposite views. Family benefits are virtually nonexistent in the United States with the exception of particularly low-income families allocated under the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program. Regardless of income, benefits are available to everyone in Germany and Sweden. Healthcare is probably the service with the greatest variation between America and Europe. Germany and Sweden offer unlimited universal coverage. This means that the government pays for visits to the doctor, hospitalization, and pharmaceutical products with minimal deductibles. The United States, on the other hand, is solely reliable on Medicare and Medicaid for just a select portion of the population. Medicare is a program designed specifically for the elderly, whereas Medicaid is intended for the needy. As far as sickness and accidental injury benefits, there is no federal relief in the United States. Only five states offer some kind of sickness benefit. If the household’s primary income holder fell ill in the United States, he or she would only be guaranteed between 18 to 63 percent of the average wage (Alesina et al., 2001, page 10). This benefit would last for a maximum of fifty-two weeks. If the same household’s primary income holder fell ill in Germany, then seventy percent of gross earnings would be covered by benefits for up to seventy-eight weeks (Alesina et al., 2001, page 10). In Sweden, the same person would receive eighty percent of gross earnings under the country’s benefit plan indefinitely (Alesina et al., 2001, page 10). In terms of on-the-job accidental injury, the United States and most of Europe is covered similarly with generous supplemental considerations.

Germany relies on Sozialhilfe and Sweden on Socialbidrag to alleviate poverty within their countries. Both of these plans are unlimited and unconditional. The welfare system in America is not aimed at helping the impoverished, but rather works to give the low-income families and disabled persons employment opportunities with the hope that opportunity will breed personal success. Thus, various programs are targeted for different groups in America. One such program is the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program, mentioned above. Additionally, the Supplemental Security Income (SSI) is intended for the aged, blind, disabled, or people with an income of less than $5,808 (Alesina et al., 2001, page 10).

Historically speaking, there are two prominent events that distinguish America from Europe: the “wild west” movement and the absence of a strong socialist political party. The movement of Americans stretching across the continent to the Pacific Ocean marks a passage unlike anything Europe ever witnessed. The open frontier stressed individualism and personal benefits through opportunity. Through this, people came to accept that in America there is no equal outcome. One may even go as far as to call this social Darwinism or a self-selection process of sorts. As America saw people moving west, urban population density severely declined. Some historians argue that “urban density leads to political empowerment of the poor” (Alesina et al., 2001, page 37) which, in turn, facilitates riot and rebellion. In general, Europe has been uprooted by wars, observed numerous fallen monarchies, and made constant changes to constitutions in hope that modernity would bring security. Ultimately, these alterations grew a tendency to focus on majority rule and less on protecting private property. Comparatively speaking, these issues have never pertained to the United States as only two wars fought on American soil, and a single constitution has had minor, but necessary, amendments. The United States has had a very stable history.

Additionally, low population density in the United States meant that the American government was virtually immune to socialist revolution. This does not mean that class-related revolutions were nonexistent. Those riots took place predominately in the 1930s and 1960s across America. What is unique about the union riots of the 1930s and the racial riots of the 1960s, is that never once did these rebellions threaten central government.

More importantly though, the fact that feudal society never developed in the United States aided in preventing socialist development. Feudal society did not develop as a result of the huge influx of immigrants that willingly assumed the roles of the working class. Ethnic divisions were strongly felt, but the fact that everyone received equal opportunity over road that ethnic tension. American capitalism may have created inequality but always offered opportunity to all (Alesina et al., 2001, page 37). Furthermore, the two-party electoral system that existed in America made it virtually impossible for a third party to rise to power enabling the United States to “evolve as a federal system rather than as a unitary, centralized country like several of today’s European countries” (Alesina et al., 2001, page 38).

As is the case with many political, social, and economic dilemmas, race has become a factor is welfare debates. Social psychologists have research that shows humans are quick to form in-group and out-group associations. This is the “us versus them” syndrome. In-group associations tend to reflect group similarities. Out-groups, on the other hand, represent the antithesis of a particular in-group. For example, the median American voter is a middle class Caucasian. Members of that in-group would also be white, middle class, Americans. The out-group, for instance, could be a particular minority living in a much different social circle and income distribution. Humans in general are less inclined to give to persons of an out-group, or in this case, minorities. The bottom line is wealthy Caucasians do not want to see their tax dollars go to “lazy” or societies marginalized citizens. Since a percentage of tax money goes toward social services, it is easy to associate the poor with laziness and therefore unworthiness in America.

The race-based theory states that “Americans think of the poor as members of some different group than themselves, whereas Europeans think of the poor as members of their own group” (Alesina et al., 2001, page 43). It is natural to perceive members of “the other” group to be inferior to oneself. The United States, and most of North and South America for that matter, is more unified in language than in race. European countries tend to be racially homogeneous, and it is in these countries that there is the greatest social spending.

Americans are hesitant to aid the poor because the poor are perceived as lazy. Europeans tend to view the poor as simply unfortunate. This cultural differentiation is supported by the findings of a recent World Values Survey where “70 percent of West Germans express the belief that people are poor because of imperfections in society, not their own laziness, (while) 70 percent of Americans hold the opposite view” (Glazer, 2003, page 113). This fundamental difference in the perception of the poor is often referred to as “American Exceptionalism” (Alesina et al., 2001, page 3). But, this must be taken with a grain of salt. The World Values Survey recently reported that “71 percent of Americans, but only 40 percent of Europeans, believe that the poor have a chance to escape from poverty” (Glazer, 2003, page 133). This suggests that there is more social mobility in the United States than in Europe. Social mobility enables a citizen to do more with less, so it is only expected for someone below the poverty line in America to rise up against the adversity and beat the odds so to speak. Americans believe their citizens can work their way out of poverty. With this mentality, there is little to no concern with social safety nets in the form of a welfare state. In contrast, if less than half of Europeans believe their citizens can escape from poverty then a strong social intervention by the government in terms of social benefits and welfare services is clearly necessary.

Europeans may be more active in public provisions of welfare, but Americans are known for their contributions to the needy in the form of private provisions. Public welfare is what has been discussed in this paper thus far. In contrast, private welfare takes form in the efforts of donations, non-profit work, volunteering, etc. In 2000, estimated charitable contributions in the United States totaled $691 per capita (Glazer, 2003, page 114). This is more than twelve times greater than the per capita contributions of the European average, which amounted to a whopping $57 (Glazer, 2003, page 114). Granted, America is a country of extreme wealth and with that wealth comes large donations. But, private provisions of welfare are not all about the money exchange. Volunteer rates are higher in the United States than in Europe as well. Eleven percent of surveyed Americans, compared to four percent of Europeans, said they participated in a charitable group within the past year (Glazer, 2003, page 114). The Netherlands had the highest percentage of volunteer work on the continent with a total of 8.6 percent (Glazer, 2003, page 114). It is possible that Americans are more comfortable in private relief because Americans can choose how their money helps people. In terms of public provisions, it is not always clear where the money is truthfully going. This touches on a whole other topic of skepticism in the welfare state.

The established electoral systems in Europe and the United States appear to have a strong influence on the strength of welfare policy. Most of Europe functions under the Proportional Representation (PR) electoral system. This allows for marginal differences in seat chairs versus vote chairs, thus enabling small party survival. The multi-party party system is attached with the PR electoral system. Ultimately, this manifests either coalition governments or minority governments. In contrast, the United States operates under the Single Member District (SMD) electoral system. This structure tends to penalize small parties because victory is often exaggerated. Only two parties survive in the party system. Thus, the government is a single party majority government. The United Kingdom is not like the rest of Europe in electoral policy, as the United Kingdom hosts an SMD system. Even-so, the SMD system in the United Kingdom gives minorities more opportunities for power and political expression than minorities in the United States. Overall, the poor have greater representation in Europe due to the Proportional Representation system established there.

The low-income households and disabled are typically the minority in society. Given that the PR system allows minority power to thrive, it is in countries that house this electoral system that action for minorities is taken seriously and effectively. Additionally, in the United States where the SMD system thrives and minority power is squashed, there is learned helplessness, pessimism, and a lack of faith in public policy. It is conclusive that the specific type of electoral system within a country shapes the state of welfare within that particular country.

Conclusion

America’s deviation from a European-style welfare state is the result of a unique history, low population density and a federal system that prevented socialist ideals, greater social mobility for the marginalized, strength of private provisions over public provisions, and the SMD electoral system within the country. All of these aspects skew America’s welfare system. Europe has established an effective and efficient structure to help not just the low-income households or the disabled, but the entire population indefinitely.
Works Cited
Alesina Alberto, Edward Glaeser, and Bruce Sacerdote. "Why Doesn't the United States have a European-style Welfare State?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2001). 5 Oct. 2005. 1-70.
Faher, Nicole. "United Kingdom." Country Case Studies and Links. 2000. University of Pittsburgh at Johnstown. 2 Oct. 2005 .
Glazer, Nathan. "Nathan Glazer on Americans and Inequality." Doedalus (2003): 111-115. 5 Oct. 2005.
Hander, Joel F. Social citizenship and workfare in the United States and Western Europe : the paradox of inclusion. New York: Cambridge UP, 2004. 11-170.
Kesselman, Mark, Joel Krieger, and William A. Joseph. Introduction to Comparative Politics. 3rdrd ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 2004. 25-344.
Rothstein, Bo. Just institutions matter : the moral and political logic of the universal welfare state. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge UP, 1998. 57-165.
Sakamoto, Takayuki. Political Science. McGraw-Hill, 2005. 101-110.
"Social Policy in the UK." An Introduction to Social Policy. 2 Oct. 2005 .
Yergin, Daniel, and Joseph Stanislaw. The Commanding Heights. New York, 1998. 22-25.

http://encarta.msn.com/text_761575466__1/Welfare.html
History of Welfare

Welfare systems are formalized versions of types of social support that societies have always maintained. In all societies since the beginning of civilization, able-bodied adults have worked to support themselves as well as to provide for young, elderly, and disabled family members and, often, nonfamily members. In ancient societies nonproductive members (the elderly, the disabled, and weaker children) seldom survived for long; in some cases, they were sacrificed for the good of the whole. By the Middle Ages in Europe, such vulnerable individuals were surviving longer and societies began to establish formal economic arrangements for giving charity to those in need. Donations by churches and from local feudal lords and other wealthy individuals supported hospitals, orphanages, and almshouses (publicly funded homes for the poor).

A. The English Poor Laws

The English Poor Laws, a system set up by the government of England in the late 16th and early 17th centuries, attempted to establish a clear public responsibility for care of the poor. Under these laws, government authorities divided the poor into two groups. The “deserving poor” were those deemed unable to work—primarily the disabled, blind, and elderly. The able-bodied unemployed were labeled the “undeserving poor.” Those considered unable to work were generally eligible for cash or other forms of assistance in their homes, known as outdoor relief. Those who could work were provided with what amounted to public-service employment. Such government-funded work was known as indoor relief, because it was usually done inside large public facilities called workhouses. As a last resort, some of those unable to work and provide for themselves sought refuge in poorhouses or almshouses, publicly funded institutions that offered food and shelter.

The Poor Laws made local government the primary administrator of welfare. To keep welfare beneficiaries under the supervision of their providers, the laws also discouraged the migration of the poor among administrative regions, or parishes. From their inception, the Poor Laws generated controversy. Opponents of the laws argued that if the poor received public assistance, some of them might avoid work, not work hard enough, or not save any of their earnings.

Despite such criticism, some Poor Law administrators hoped they could prevent welfare dependency by making people work for benefits. In a major work initiative begun in the late 1700s, administrators assigned relief recipients to work at private farms and businesses. Public funds were used to supplement the wages of those assigned to this work requirement and to those privately employed at starvation wages. This plan became known as the Speenhamland System, after the British parish in which it was pioneered.

In the late 1830s, many local governments also established workhouses, where the able-bodied poor worked when no private work was available. Workhouses were often made to be unpleasant places, so that people would seek even meagerly paid menial jobs before taking workhouse employment.

B. Other Early Programs in Europe

In the late 19th century several European countries instituted social insurance programs. These programs alleviated some of the risks of living and working in rapidly industrializing societies. Governments typically financed social insurance programs with tax funds and direct levies on the wages of potential recipients. Social insurance replaced part of incomes lost when workers became disabled, were laid off, or had reached an age that forced them out of the labor market.

Later, governments of Germany, France, Belgium, Sweden, and other countries developed forms of social insurance that provided population-wide, or universal, coverage. Such forms included children’s allowances, universal health coverage, broadly available childcare, generous aid to those seeking post-secondary education, and other programs that provided income and other essential supports to all citizens. In much of Europe, social insurance programs came to be seen as desirable alternatives to forms of welfare associated with the Poor Laws.

C. Early Welfare Programs in the United States

The American colonists essentially imported the framework of the British Poor Laws. By the early 19th century, states required that counties or municipalities provide for the poor and needy. The local governments carried out this responsibility in one of four ways: by auctioning off the poor to bidders who could use them as workers; by contracting with wealthier families to take care of them, either as charitable acts or for pay or free labor; by placing the poor and needy in public institutions (workhouses); or by providing them with assistance in cash or goods.

Citizens and politicians publicly expressed their concerns about welfare from the country’s beginnings. In the 1820s and 1830s, a reform movement swept many states. Local communities tried to replace all outdoor relief—the giving of cash and goods to the poor—with workhouses. These reforms were intended to rehabilitate the poor and replace frivolous welfare use with a work ethic.

In the 1880s and 1890s, a second wave of reform efforts designed to curb the use of outdoor relief emerged. The scientific charity reform movement emphasized counseling the poor to improve their social functioning. Reformers also encouraged independence through social casework. In this approach, caseworkers visited poor people regularly and instructed them in morality and a work ethic. Supporters of scientific charity opposed the idea of unconditional relief. In some parts of the country these reformers were able to temporarily halt distributions of cash relief almost entirely.

Welfare did not disappear, however. From the mid-1800s to the early 1900s, the Congress of the United States sponsored various programs that expanded public provision for the poor. In 1862 Congress passed legislation for a Civil War Pension Program, which eventually made economic, disability, and old-age benefits available to all Civil War veterans and their families. Between 1911 and 1921, 40 states established mothers’ pensions. In these programs, states offered income support to poor mothers, mostly widows, upholding the notion that motherhood was appropriate as a sole occupation. In the early 20th century, a handful of states experimented with workers’ compensation programs to insure workers against industrial accidents and with unemployment compensation programs to insure workers against labor market uncertainties.

D. Development of the Modern U.S. Welfare System

The modern U.S. welfare system dates to the Great Depression of the 1930s. During the worst parts of the depression, about one-fourth of the labor force was without work. More than two-thirds of all households would have been considered poor by today’s standards (adjusted for inflationary changes in the value of the U.S. dollar). With a majority of the able-bodied adult population experiencing severe financial distress firsthand, Americans no longer could view poverty simply as a personal failing.

U.S. president Franklin D. Roosevelt led a social and economic reform movement as a response to the depression. Part of his New Deal program was the Social Security Act, enacted by Congress in 1935. This act and its 1939 amendments established a number of social welfare programs, each designed to provide support for different segments of the population. Programs included Old-Age and Survivors’ Insurance (OASI) for retired people and their families (to which disability insurance was added in 1954, forming OASDI); Unemployment Compensation for those who lost work temporarily; Aid to Dependent Children (ADC), later known as Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC); and grants to states to provide medical care. In 1946 the government created the Social Security Administration (SSA) to oversee the provisions of the act.

A succession of federal agencies have administered social security programs since the act’s inception. The Federal Security Agency was established in 1939; the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare in 1953; and the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) in 1980, when the SSA became a separate organization. The government created the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) in 1965. It replaced the former Housing and Home Finance Agency, and provides public housing support for low-income families. The U.S. Department of Labor—created in 1913, predating the Social Security Act—and its Pension and Welfare Benefits Administration manages workers’ benefits programs. Its Employment and Training Administration manages some welfare-to-work programs, as well as job training and placement programs. Other federal government agencies, including the Department of Education, the Department of Agriculture, and the Department of the Treasury, also administer welfare programs.

Funding for welfare programs has significantly increased in recent decades, particularly for working families who remain poor. In 1999, for example, the U.S. government spent $52 billion on a range of supports for low-income working families through tax credits, help with childcare, and other assistance. By contrast, the government spent only $6 billion on comparable programs in 1984, even after accounting for inflation.

IV. Forms of Welfare in the United States

The U.S. government provides welfare in a number of basic ways. Some programs distribute direct cash assistance that recipients may spend as they choose. Other programs provide specific goods, such as public housing; or the means to obtain them, such as subsidized rents, vouchers to offset private housing costs, or coupons to purchase food. Still others provide services or the means to obtain services. Welfare services include health care, childcare, and help coping with drug or alcohol dependency. Goods and services, as opposed to direct cash assistance, are known as in-kind benefits. Other welfare programs create or subsidize jobs for the unemployed. In addition, the government also provides a tax discount to the poor, known as an Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), which some people consider a welfare program. If calculated as an expenditure—although it is in part actually money the government does not collect—EITC is one of the more costly U.S. welfare programs, with expenditures exceeding $30 billion annually.

In the United States, as in many other nations, the government decides how much welfare support to provide, and to whom, based on measures of economic well-being. These measures are themselves based on national mean income figures. Mean income is an estimate of how much a typical person earns over a given period of time, usually a year. People whose incomes are less than a determined amount below the national mean are considered to be living in poverty. Welfare programs targeted to people with relatively little income and few assets are called means-tested welfare programs. Other forms of income support are referred to simply as non-means-tested.

In virtually all cash welfare programs and many in-kind programs, benefits rapidly fall as a recipient’s income increases. These programs are said to be targeted, or restricted, to people with little or no income and few assets. Some programs further restrict benefits to those meeting additional, nonincome requirements, known as categorical targets. For example, benefits might depend on a recipient being a single parent with dependent children or a juvenile in foster care.

Eligibility for certain forms of welfare is based on membership in specific groups. The elderly and people with mental or physical disabilities, for example, receive several types of support that the government provides specifically to them. Eligibility for social insurance programs, meanwhile, depends upon individuals having made prior financial contributions to a fund, which can be drawn on later. The most prominent examples of this form of welfare in the United States are social security programs. These programs provide support to workers and their families when they lose employment, retire, or become disabled.

In theory, welfare targets make sense, since they direct support to those most in need. Targeting, however, creates problematic incentives. For example, if welfare recipients begin to earn money, or more money than they had been earning, their benefits may fall and their taxes rise. This can be a powerful incentive for recipients to remain on welfare and not seek work. In effect, this situation creates a penalty for welfare recipients who take work, especially in any of the many low-wage jobs typically available to them. Working at a minimal wage, minus taxes, often cannot offset the loss of welfare benefits. Targeting welfare benefits to certain groups also creates incentives for people to change their behavior in order to become eligible for benefits. A young parent may be less inclined to marry or stay married if single parenthood makes it easier to claim welfare benefits. The dilemma of balancing compassion for the poor with a desire to promote socially approved behaviors—work and marriage, for example—has defined public policy debates over welfare for several centuries.

A. Cash Assistance Programs

In the decades following the passage of the Social Security Act, the scope of the United States’s social welfare safety net grew, modestly at first and then more rapidly beginning in the 1960s. By the beginning of the 1990s, there were about 75 means-tested welfare programs. This collection of programs came to be symbolized, however, by the one known as Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC), which provided cash assistance to parents and children in need of economic support due to the death, continued absence, or incapacity of the family’s primary wage earner (typically the father).

For a quarter-century AFDC remained a relatively small, obscure program. In 1960 fewer than 4 percent of children received AFDC benefits in a typical month, even though about 25 percent would have been considered poor by today’s standards. In 1996, 7.9 million children, almost 13 percent of all children, and about 3.9 million adults received help from AFDC in any given month. As the program grew, it became increasingly unpopular. Critics argued that AFDC discouraged work, encouraged births outside of marriage, and failed to take low-income families with children out of poverty.

In 1996 AFDC cost about $22 billion per year, about 55 percent of that cost covered by the federal government and the rest by state and local governments. This expenditure was a minor part of the U.S. annual budget. Remarkably, although AFDC caseloads rose, the overall costs of the program remained the same from the early 1970s, even after considering inflation. This was possible only because typical benefits fell in value, by about half, after 1970. The average monthly benefit in 1995 was $377, about 60 percent below poverty-level income for most families. Moreover, the size of the typical AFDC family fell from about four members in the late 1960s to less than three in 1994. Larger families received higher benefits than smaller ones, but only marginally so. Some critics of AFDC claimed, however, that this could have been an incentive for parents on welfare to have more children.

In the first half of the 1990s, a national debate raged about how to reform welfare, and particularly AFDC. Finally, in August 1996, President Bill Clinton signed the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA), which replaced AFDC with the Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) program. Among other things, TANF ended the guarantee of cash benefits to eligible families, established a fixed federal contribution to the program, imposed time limits and strict work requirements, and transferred most program decisions to the states. (For more information on these reforms, see the Welfare Reform section of this article.)

Low-income families with children are not the only group eligible for cash assistance. Adults who are not able to work because of age, blindness, or disability, as well as some disabled children, can receive cash assistance through Supplemental Security Income (SSI). SSI provides more generous assistance than TANF. In 2003 individuals received $552 monthly, roughly 25 percent below poverty-level income, and couples received $829 monthly, or about 18 percent below poverty level. The number of people receiving SSI payments had grown to about 6.5 million by 1995; participation has since remained stable. The federal government spent $33.3 billion on the program in 2001.

B. In-Kind Assistance Programs

Most people on welfare receive more than just cash assistance. For example, many low-income families receive some form of food or nutritional assistance from the government. Cash welfare recipients often participate in programs that provide health services, particularly for their children. More than one-fourth of cash welfare recipients have received housing assistance or live in public housing, and an increasing proportion now participate in programs designed to help them find work.

Medicaid provides medical assistance for people who live in low-income families with dependent children and for individuals with low incomes who are elderly or disabled. Between 1986 and 1991, Congress extended Medicaid coverage to support pregnant women and some children who have no other ties to the welfare system. In 2001 Medicaid covered approximately 34 million people, or about 12 percent of the total U.S. population. Nearly 50 percent of Medicaid enrollees were children. The cost of the program has grown faster than the rate of inflation and was estimated to be $228 billion in 2001. Slightly more than half of that was paid for by the federal government, with the rest covered by state funds.

In 1965 U.S. president Lyndon B. Johnson declared a War on Poverty in his domestic reform program called the Great Society. As part of this program, Congress established Medicare, a social insurance counterpart to Medicaid. Medicare provides medical pensions for all retired U.S. citizens and a small segment of the disabled. The program cost $242 billion in 2001 and covered about 40 million people.

The Food Stamp program, administered by the U.S. Department of Agriculture and financed through the Social Security Administration, provides families with vouchers or electronic benefit cards to purchase food. This benefit is available to both low-income families with dependent children and households without children. The food stamps supplement what participants would normally spend on food, thereby enabling them to obtain an adequate diet. In a typical month in 2001, more than 17 million households participated in the Food Stamp program. Millions of low-income children also receive nutritional help through the National School Lunch Program and the School Breakfast Program, which provide low-cost or free meals to eligible children each school day.

The federal Department of Housing and Urban Development offers a number of programs that provide housing assistance to low-income families. Unlike some other welfare programs, there is no entitlement to this kind of assistance. An entitlement is support that the government must provide if a person qualifies as eligible according to income, assets, and categorical eligibility standards. People who meet eligibility requirements must formally apply for housing assistance, but have no guarantee they will receive it. The government provides eligible applicants with various housing options. They may be provided with apartments in housing projects specifically built for low-income families or adults. Alternately, they may receive subsidized rent in apartments or housing complexes where some of the units are reserved for the poor, or they may receive vouchers that they can use to offset housing costs.

The federal government sponsors a number of other programs for various poor and disadvantaged groups. These include the Women, Infants, and Children (WIC) program, which provides supplemental food and nutrition information primarily to pregnant women and infants who are at risk of nutritional deficiency; various job-training and job-seeking assistance programs; the Head Start early education program for disadvantaged children; the Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP); supports for former war veterans; and many others.

C. General Assistance

No federal cash welfare programs exist for people who are clearly able to work—single adults and couples who have no dependent children and who are not eligible for a disability program. However, some states or local governments may provide help for such people under what are called General Assistance (GA) programs. Where they exist, GA programs commonly provide limited economic supports and subsidies for medical care.

V. Welfare Reform

The general public and government representatives at all levels have grown increasingly critical of the U.S. welfare system during the last few decades. President Johnson’s War on Poverty failed to fully live up to its goals of eradicating unemployment and poverty among those who were not sharing in the post-World War II period of prosperity. In the 1970s and 1980s, many poor people became dependent on welfare, particularly on means-tested and targeted programs, such as the Food Stamp program and AFDC.

By the mid-1990s the government had struggled to reform AFDC, in particular, for almost three decades. Most welfare reform efforts have been motivated by public concerns that welfare causes undesirable behaviors. Many citizens and politicians claim that welfare conditions its recipients to have little motivation to work, to avoid or break marriages, and to have children when they are too young and unprepared. Some reformers, on the other hand, argue that existing welfare programs are woefully inadequate and do not raise recipients out of poverty, particularly the children of families receiving benefits.

In 1996 President Bill Clinton signed the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA). PRWORA most directly affected the provisions of AFDC (and JOBS, AFDC’s auxiliary work program), which were both replaced by the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program. PRWORA also affected the Food Stamp program, especially its provisions for assistance to adults with no children.

Before PRWORA, the federal government had established eligibility criteria for AFDC benefits and guidelines for the JOBS program. States determined their own benefit levels, which were applied uniformly to all families in similar circumstances. The federal government matched each state’s funds.

In the reform program, the federal government gives annual block grants, or lump sums, to states. Whereas AFDC was an entitlement for recipients, TANF is not. It is an entitlement only for state governments. States may decide how potential recipients must apply for eligibility, and support to eligible applicants is not guaranteed. In addition, AFDC recipients could receive benefits as long as they met eligibility requirements. Under TANF, federal funds cannot be used to provide benefits to families who have been on assistance for five years, with a few exceptions. Furthermore, states must require TANF recipients to work after two years of assistance or the states will lose some of their federal TANF funding. To meet these requirements, states must continue to fund job training, subsidized employment, and childcare programs.

Overall, TANF removes power from the federal government and gives it to the states, reducing the importance of any national policy on how welfare should be handled. The reform program aims to reduce AFDC-type welfare dependency and encourage parents to shift from welfare to work.

Most authorities agree that TANF has worked better than expected, although areas of criticism remain. The TANF caseload dropped from 5 million cases in 1994 to 2.1 million cases in 2001. Participation in the labor force by single mothers, the group targeted by TANF, jumped from 58 percent in 1993 to 74 percent in 2000. The proportion of TANF participants working at least part-time tripled from 11 percent in 1996 to 33 percent in 1999. At the same time, overall poverty and child poverty decreased. Black child poverty fell to its lowest rate in 2000; and the poverty rate among female-headed families fell from 39 percent in 1994 to 30.4 percent in 2000. Finally, the proportion of births to unmarried mothers leveled off in the late 1990s after almost four decades of continuous increases.

Critics point out, however, that many families have left welfare without adequate incomes. Of those leaving welfare, perhaps as many as 20 percent are not earning money or are living with others who are supporting them. Many of these individuals were forced off welfare for not complying with the rules or for exceeding federal or state time limits. Thus, there is some evidence that the most needy families are not faring well under the new reforms.

VI. Welfare in Canada

Canada, much like the United States, imported some aspects of the British Poor Laws. In that tradition, administration of welfare programs in Canada has always been partly regional. Provincial and territorial governments play a significant role in setting policy and administering welfare programs.

A. Changing Welfare Needs

Since the 1980s Canada has experienced fundamental changes in its social and economic structure. The labor market has changed substantially, and the unemployment rate has climbed considerably since the end of World War II in 1945. The rate averaged more than 10 percent in the 1990s, up from about 4 percent in the 1950s.

As is the case in the United States, fewer full-time, permanent jobs are available than in the past, and the education and skill levels required to obtain these jobs has increased. In addition, the employable population is growing with women joining the workforce and increasing numbers of immigrants to Canada. The proportion of two-income families has increased by half in the past quarter-century to over 60 percent of all families.

The proportion of single-parent families also increased from about 11 percent of all families at the beginning of the 1980s to about 15 percent in early 1996. Available data suggest that almost 60 percent of Canadian children in single-parent families are poor and probably need welfare support, compared with 12 percent living with both parents.

In the 1990s rising welfare use and costs fueled calls for reform. Across the country, welfare recipients increased by 63 percent between 1989 and 1995. Also, government social expenditures and the cost of social insurance rose dramatically between the 1960s and the 1990s. Increasingly, Canada’s federal and regional governments have sought to scale back benefits and move unemployed recipients into the labor force. Mirroring developments in the United States, in the late 1990s the Canadian federal government embarked upon radical and often controversial reforms of Canada’s welfare programs.

B. Social Assistance

Canada’s primary welfare system, called Social Assistance (SA), encompasses a number of programs. The federal government set the structure of the SA system with the passage of the Canada Assistance Plan (CAP) in 1966. Parts of SA resemble the former AFDC program in the United States, but SA is much more comprehensive and covers more types of households. Between the early 1980s and the early 1990s, recipients of SA doubled from about 1.5 million people to about 3 million. The legislation for SA also laid out arrangements for the division of welfare administration between the federal and regional governments. Canada’s provincial and territorial governments determined SA needs and managed distributions, while funding and broad policymaking were split between the federal and regional levels.

As part of its reforms in 1996 and 1997, the Canadian government is changing how it administers SA. In the newer system, called Canada Health and Social Transfer, the federal government gives block grants to provinces and territories.

C. Unemployment Insurance

In the early 1970s, the Canadian government greatly expanded the country’s Unemployment Insurance (UI) program, which had existed in other forms since 1940. UI became the most widely used Canadian social security program for adults. The program provides assistance to both unemployed and working Canadians as a supplement, with benefits exceeding those in most other developed nations.

Annual costs for the UI program roughly doubled between 1973 and 1994. In 1996 the federal government reformed UI and renamed it Employment Insurance. This new program of federal block grants to provinces and territories gave work incentives to people having difficulty finding desirable full-time jobs by providing wage supplements to part-time workers. It also provided funding for employers to create jobs, subsidies to employers who hired welfare recipients, and job-seeking assistance.

D. Universal Health Care

The Canadian welfare system is also strongly focused on providing health care to citizens. Between the mid-1950s and the 1970s, Canada’s federal, provincial, and territorial governments progressively joined together to create nationwide health-care programs and programs for the elderly. Unlike U.S. citizens, all Canadians receive health care as part of a national plan. Canada’s Medicare program—no relation to U.S. Medicare—is known as a single-payer system, and is funded primarily by income, corporate, sales, and other taxes. The governments, the so-called single payers, then fund private health-care providers to supply all basic and emergency medical services. Some services remain privately funded.

VII. Programs in Other Developed Countries

Relative to the United States, and to some extent Canada, the social welfare systems in other developed countries, especially in western Europe, are far more comprehensive and better financed. In particular, the Scandinavian countries, Australia, and New Zealand have developed generous public assistance programs.

Except for the United States and South Africa, all developed countries guarantee health-care access to all citizens or subsidize national health care. Coverage often includes both sickness and maternity support. Some nations, including the United Kingdom and the Russian Federation, provide the care directly through some form of national health service, in which the government administers health care through public facilities. Other countries, such as New Zealand and Australia, distribute public funds for privately provided health care.

Several developed countries have established a variety of other programs that are available to all citizens. Money for these programs comes primarily from general government funds. Some of these programs provide support to everyone, rich and poor alike, while others are means-tested or otherwise restricted. For example, Australia, New Zealand, Israel, many western European countries (the United Kingdom, Ireland, Germany, France, and the Scandinavian countries, for example), and some in eastern Europe (for instance, the Russian Federation, Poland, and Romania) offer family allowances. These are payments made to parents to offset some of the costs of raising children. In some cases these programs provide benefits to adult dependents who do not work in the formal economy, such as homemakers, or who continue in school or apprenticeships. In much of Europe, childcare is widely available and publicly subsidized. A few developed countries—such as Australia, New Zealand, and some of the Scandinavian countries—offer universal old age, disability, and survivor benefits. Many governments also subsidize training for workers.

Since international comparisons of poverty were first begun with the Luxembourg Income Study in the early 1980s, it has been found that all other developed nations have lower poverty rates than the United States, particularly for children. For example, poverty rates for children in France have been about four times lower than those in the United States. In Sweden, less than 10 percent of children living with a single parent are poor, while over half of single-parent children in the United States live in poverty.

Achieving low poverty rates can be costly, however. Sweden and Denmark, for instance, spend slightly more than 50 percent of their gross domestic product (GDP) on forms of public support. In France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and many other countries, citizens and politicians question whether their national welfare systems can be maintained into the indefinite future.

Not surprisingly, many European countries—including the United Kingdom, France, The Netherlands, and Denmark—have recently discussed whether U.S.-style reforms that emphasize personal responsibility and work are appropriate for them. The common theme in policy proposals in Europe is to combat what many Europeans call “social exclusion,” the situation in which certain vulnerable groups do not fully participate in society. Policymakers tend to favor initiatives designed to facilitate full participation in society, not necessarily to reduce dependency on government.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Contributed By:
Thomas J. Corbett, B.A., M.A., Ph.D.
Assistant Professor, School of Social Work, and Associate Director, Institute for Research on Poverty, University of Wisconsin-Madison. Coeditor of Welfare Reform: Can Government Promote Parental Self-Sufficiency While Ensuring the Well-Being of Children? Author of portions of President Bill Clinton’s welfare reform bill, the Work and Responsibility Act of 1994.
"Welfare," Microsoft® Encarta® Online Encyclopedia 2006
http://encarta.msn.com © 1997-2006 Microsoft Corporation. All Rights Reserved.
© 1993-2006 Microsoft Corporation. All Rights Reserved.


Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
Author(s): Isabel V. Sawhill
Other Availability: Order Online | Printer-Friendly Page
Posted to Web: May 01, 1995
Permanent Link: http://www.urban.org/url.cfm?ID=306620
The nonpartisan Urban Institute publishes studies, reports, and books on timely topics worthy of public consideration. The views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Urban Institute, its trustees, or its funders.

INTRODUCTION

No one likes the current welfare system. Governors complain that federal law is overly prescriptive and are willing to take less federal money in return for more flexibility. The public believes that welfare is anti-work and anti-family although polls show that the public wants welfare reformed in ways that do not penalize children. Welfare recipients find dealing with the system degrading and demoralizing; most would prefer to work1. Experts note that welfare has done little to stem the growth of poverty among children. In all but two states, welfare benefits (including food stamps) are insufficient to move a family above the poverty line2.

In short, the current indictment against the welfare system has four particulars:

It does not provide sufficient state flexibility.
It does not encourage work.
It is responsible for the breakdown of the family, especially for a rising tide of out-of-wedlock births.
It has done little to reduce poverty, especially among children.
The chapters in this volume address how much truth there is in these propositions and assess the ability of current proposals to deal with the complaints. To summarize the findings at the outset:

PROVIDING STATE FLEXIBILITY: States already have substantial flexibility; they could be provided more without eliminating the current federal role in securing a safety net for the poor. Block grants will lead to new inequities and to insufficient public accountability.

ENCOURAGING WORK: Encouraging work among welfare recipients necessitates that funds be provided for this purpose. But, according to several authors, what is required is not so much major new investments in education and training as resources devoted to helping people find jobs in the private sector.

One way to encourage work is to cut off cash assistance. A set of proposals similar to the House-passed Personal Responsibility Act (PRA) ultimately would deny benefits to about 42 percent of the current caseload and reduce benefits for an additional 30 percent. But because of their poor education and other characteristics, most of those denied assistance would have difficulty finding and holding jobs. Based on the experience of those terminated from General Assistance in Michigan, as many as two-thirds could remain unemployed.

REDUCING OUT-OF-WEDLOCK BIRTHS: The majority of women on welfare had their first child as a teenager. Most of these births now occur outside of marriage and are unintended. However, there is little support in the research literature for the proposition that denying benefits to this group will prevent such pregnancies from occurring. Modest impacts on marriage and abortion are more likely.

REDUCING CHILD POVERTY: Moving more children out of poverty requires that income from a low-wage job be combined with child care, health insurance, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and support from both parents. Child support reform in particular could reduce poverty and welfare costs as much as anything else that recently has been proposed.

At the same time, for budgetary reasons the broader safety net is predicted to shrink. The PRA alone provides 13 percent of the total five-year savings in the House budget resolution. Thus, even if no other low-income program such as Medicaid were affected by attempts to balance the budget, the poorest fifth of the population (which receives 4 percent of total U.S. income) would bear a disproportionate share of the burden.

In sum, measured against the objectives of providing adequate flexibility to the states, encouraging work, strengthening the family, and reducing poverty, most current proposals are found wanting.

LEGISLATIVE HISTORY
While there is considerable consensus that welfare needs to be reformed, there is less agreement about exactly what needs to be done and a long history of past attempts that have proved less than satisfactory or had little staying power.

The most recent round of reform occurred in 1988, when Congress enacted the Family Support Act. It combined an emphasis on moving people into jobs with increased funding for the education and training believed necessary to make this possible. The education and training were to be provided by a new program called Job Opportunities and Basic Skills (JOBS) in which most welfare recipients would be required to participate. Many states are only now beginning to implement fully the philosophy and work-oriented programs contained in the Family Support Act. Nationwide, about 23 percent of able-bodied welfare recipients without a child under age 3 are now participating in JOBS.

As a governor, President Clinton was a strong proponent of the Family Support Act, but he campaigned for the presidency on a pledge to "end welfare as we know it." Legislation embodying the details of his plan was introduced in 1994 as the Work and Responsibility Act. It built on the Family Support Act philosophy by investing still more in education and training but set a two-year time limit, after which welfare recipients would either have to work or lose their benefits. With appropriate assistance and the push of a time limit, it was hoped that most recipients would find jobs before their two years were up, but for those who did not, subsidized work opportunities were to be made available. The two-year limit was to be phased in slowly, starting with those born after 1971. This phase-in had three advantages: it sent a message of personal responsibility to the younger generation; it gave states time to expand their ability to provide the necessary training and work opportunities; and it made the budgetary costs of the plan more manageable.

The Clinton plan was eclipsed, first by the focus on health care reform, and later by the 1994 election which led Republicans in the House to propose a new plan, the Personal Responsibility Act, which differed sharply not only from Clinton's plan but also from their own earlier reform proposals. The PRA, enacted by the House on March 24, 1995, goes far beyond simply reforming welfare. It creates a number of new block grants focused on cash assistance, child nutrition, child protection, and child care. It also contains fundamental reforms of the Food Stamp program, Supplemental Security Income (SSI) for the low-income disabled, and the major means-tested programs serving legal immigrants. Overall, it saves almost $70 billion over the next five years (see figure). Its more narrowly defined "welfare" component not only turns the current Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) and JOBS programs into a block grant with flat funding for the next five years, but also contains a number of prohibitions. Notably, no federal funds are to be used to pay benefits to unwed minor mothers, to children born to mothers on welfare, or to those receiving welfare for more than five years.

Most governors strongly support the increased flexibility inherent in block grants but are unhappy with the prospect of new federal prohibitions and privately nervous about the implicit cost shifting to lower levels of government 3. As this goes to press, the Senate Finance Committee has endorsed the block grant approach adopted by the House but has omitted some of the prohibitions most disliked by governors.

Whatever the outcome of the legislative process, the chapters in this volume make one thing abundantly clear: the issues are much more complex and reform much more difficult than is generally recognized. Predicting the consequences of reform is equally difficult, a problem with which all of the authors of this volume have had to grapple.

ISSUE ONE: THE FEDERAL ROLE IN MAINTAINING A SAFETY NET

ISSUE TWO: ENCOURAGING WORK
ISSUE THREE: THE EFFECTS OF TIME LIMITS
ISSUE FOUR: PREVENTING DEPENDENCY
ISSUE FIVE: THE BROADER SAFETY NET

FINAL ASSESSMENT
Congress is now deliberating legislative and budgetary changes that would dramatically redefine the nation's responsibilities for the least advantaged. Debate about these responsibilities should be welcomed and new ideas given careful consideration. It is not written in stone or in the Constitution that the federal government needs to take care of the poor. Current programs are widely viewed as deficient, in large part because they are perceived as encouraging dependency and the dissolution of the family. In some areas, the federal role has become too intrusive. And without new taxes, money is in short supply. Returning responsibility to the states with a tie-off grant from the federal government to ease the transition is seen by many as the solution.

In my own view, arguments that current proposals are the best means of dealing with these problems are somewhat disingenuous. As many have argued, these proposals could more accurately be described as a Trojan horse designed to dismantle the welfare state that has existed for the past 60 years. If the objective is to encourage work and marriage, these reforms send the right signals but may disappoint in practice. If the objective is to provide states with greater flexibility, the solution is a streamlined waiver process and other modest reforms. States already have a great deal of flexibility and could readily be given more within a framework that establishes minimum protections for the poor and accountability for the public's money.

If the objective is to reduce the deficit, this could be achieved without cutting so deeply into programs that help the most vulnerable. The poorest 20 percent of the population now receives roughly 4 percent of all income in the United States. Any deficit reduction package that asks them to pay more than 4 percent of the total burden is arguably unfair. Yet chances are that they will end up paying far more than this. Deficit reduction is a worthy goal, but numerous tax subsidies and entitlement programs could be tapped before low-income programs were cut. As it is, safety-net programs are being restructured in ways that not only yield federal savings but also promise less state effort as well.

Finally, if the objective is to reduce poverty without encouraging dependency, the most important thing that government can do is to assist low-income working families with such measures as the EITC, child care, subsidized health insurance, and adjustments in the minimum wage. If personal commitments to work and family are the surest way out of poverty, as they have been in the past, then these work-oriented measures are the best way to keep those who play by the rules from falling further behind.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Contents

Chapter 1: A Block Grant Approach to Welfare Reform by George Peterson
Chapter 2: State Response to Welfare Reform: A Race to the Bottom? by Paul Peterson
Chapter 3:Rainy Day Funds: Contingency Funding for Welfare Block Grants by Wayne Vroman
Chapter 4: Increasing the Employment and Earnings of Welfare Recipients by Robert Lerman
Chapter 5: An Administrative Approach to Welfare Reform by Lawrence M. Mead
Chapter 6: Child Care Block Grants and Welfare Reform by Sandra Clark and Sharon Long
Chapter 7: Who is Affected by Time Limits? by LaDonna Pavetti
Chapter 8: Assessing the Personal Responsibility Act by Sheila Zedlewski and Isabel V. Sawhill
Chapter 9: Will Welfare Recipients Find Work When Welfare Ends? by Sandra K. Danziger and Sheldon Danziger
Chapter 10: Teenage Childbearing: The Trends and Their Implications by Freya L. Sonestein and Gregory Acs
Chapter 11: Do Welfare Benefits Promote Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing? by Gregory Acs
Chapter 12: The Benefits on Increased Child Support Enforcement by Elaine Sorensen
Chapter 13: The Food Stamp Program and the Safety Net by James C. Ohls
Chapter 14: Reforming the Supplemental Security Income Program for Children by Pamela Loprest
Chapter 15: When Should Immigrants Receive Public Benefits by Michael Fix and Wendy Zimmerman

1. See Joe Davidson, "Welfare Mothers Stress Importance of Building Self-Esteem If Aid System Is to Be Restructured," Wall Street Journal, May 12, 1995, p. A14.

2. Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, Overview of Entitlement Programs: 1994 Green Book, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994, p. 366.

3. See, for example, John J. Fialka, "Local Governments, Like Franklin County, Ohio, Watch for Ripple Effects of Federal Budget Ax," Wall Street Journal, May 16, 1995,p. A20.


Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
ISSUE ONE: The Federal Role in Maintaining a Safety Net
Currently, welfare (AFDC) is an entitlement under which funds flow to all eligible individuals on the basis of need. The federal government pays anywhere from 50 to 80 percent of the costs, depending on the state. Under current proposals, individuals would no longer be entitled to such assistance and states would be given a fixed amount of money that would no longer vary with the number of families needing assistance. These proposals to "block grant" federal funds and return more responsibility to the states are analyzed in the first three chapters of this volume. The authors note that the main effect would be to shift not just responsibilities but also costs to the states, which may unleash a competitive scramble among them to reduce funding for the poor.

Although such proposals are commonly referred to as "block grants," it should be noted that the term normally means a consolidation of small categorical programs with a similar mission not a capping of funds for an entitlement program. In this sense, the proposals currently being considered are unprecedented. As George Peterson notes in Chapter 1, the PRA would increase the proportion of federal aid to states given in the form of block grants from 7 to 24 percent.

These block grant proposals are intended to provide states with greater freedom from federal rules and to produce more effective programs and lower administrative costs in the process. But states already have a great deal of flexibility. Under current law, they can set benefit and eligibility levels, which results in widely different benefit levels ranging from as little as $1,440 a year for a three-person family in Mississippi to $7,284 a year in California (partially offset by federally set food stamp benefits, which are higher for those receiving smaller AFDC checks) 4. In the past, welfare reform often has focused on the need to provide more uniform benefits across the country. Current proposals, perhaps unintentionally, move in the opposite direction and would almost certainly exacerbate interstate inequities5.

Flexibility is further enhanced under current law by the fact that states can apply for waivers from federal rules. The application process is cumbersome and ought to be streamlined, but the majority of states are now operating under such waivers. One unintended consequence of reform may be to eliminate the opportunity to learn what works from the evaluations required as part of the waiver process.

The extent to which additional flexibility will reduce administrative costs is unclear, but George Peterson suggests the effects are likely to be small. (In Chapter 5, Lawrence Mead argues that if the objective is to move welfare recipients into the work force, states will need to spend more, not less, on administration of the program.)

A major concern is how states will cope should an economic downturn, a rising poverty rate, or other factors lead to greater need for assistance. The PRA contains a "rainy day" fund that is intended to address this issue. Wayne Vroman in Chapter 3 concludes that the fund as proposed is insufficient to meet the likely need. During the 1989-92 recession, for example, AFDC caseloads rose by about 11 percent. Handling a recession of this magnitude would require a rainy day fund of a little less than $3 billion, compared to the $1 billion contained in the PRA. Coping with population growth alone would require another $700 million over the next five years, in contrast to the $100 million in the PRA.

If the goal were to keep up with the growth of poor, female-headed families, the $700 million figure would need to be still larger, possibly as much as $1.7 billion. In the end, however, the most basic issue may be what Paul Peterson in Chapter 2 calls "the race to the bottom" and George Peterson calls "spiraling parsimony" the likelihood that states will reduce benefits to the poor out of a fear that they could become a haven for the most disadvantaged and drive away businesses and middle-class taxpayers in the process.

The fundamental question here is whether we should abandon the broad national purpose of reducing poverty. Those who argue for a continuing federal role do not necessarily assume that the states are uncharitable in their attitudes toward the poor. They only assume that any one state, acting generously, risks the possibility that its neighbors will not follow suit and that it will be left with disproportionate responsibility for the poor. In the absence of such "free rider" problems, there would be no role for the federal government. We could rely on states not only to help the needy but to fund all kinds of public goods. The argument is most clear-cut in the case of defense. No one doubts that if defense spending were left entirely to lower levels of government the military would be seriously underfunded. Whether a similar argument applies in the case of antipoverty spending is now the issue.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
ISSUE TWO: Encouraging Work
Virtually all recent reform proposals assume that the best alternative to welfare is work. In Chapter 4, Robert Lerman observes that policymakers have relied on a combination of three tools to increase employment and earnings: financial incentives, job search and work requirements, and education and training.

Financial incentives encourage recipients to work by allowing them to keep more of their welfare check after they go to work. (Many states are now experimenting with such incentives under federal waivers.) It would be surprising if those currently on welfare did not respond favorably to such incentives. But because such initiatives raise the income eligibility cutoff point for welfare, and thus allow more people to qualify, their net impact may be to increase rather than reduce welfare caseloads and costs. For this reason, past attempts to reduce welfare dependency by increasing the incentive to work have proved disappointing.

The other alternatives are to insist that welfare recipients work or to provide them with education and training. The evidence suggests that programs focusing on education and training produce positive results but are not as cost-effective as those that emphasize work and require people to find a job as soon as possible (with an option to pursue further education once they are headed toward self-sufficiency).

In Chapter 5, Lawrence Mead elaborates on this theme by reviewing the characteristics of successful JOBS programs in places like Riverside, California, and Kenosha, Wisconsin. He agrees with Lerman that work requirements are important and asserts that too little attention has been paid to the quality of administration at the local level, which is critical to enforcing such requirements. His research suggests that states like Wisconsin, with effective JOBS programs, have successfully reduced welfare caseloads without resorting to arbitrary time limits or other sanctions. The federal role, in his view, should be to set strong work participation requirements and to provide financial incentives for states to achieve these standards.

If a key goal of welfare reform is to move recipients into jobs, they will need day care for their children, an issue addressed by Sandra Clark and Sharon Long in Chapter 6. Their overview of current federal initiatives notes that it is the working poor who receive the least child care assistance.

The largest federal child care program is the Dependent Care Tax Credit which, because it is not refundable, provides assistance primarily to middle- and higher-income families. Several other programs focus their resources on AFDC recipients who are in training or making the transition into jobs. This leaves the Child Care and Development Block Grant as the main source of assistance for low-income working families, whose need for assistance, according to these authors, far exceeds the supply of subsidized care. Assuming that welfare reform successfully moves recipients into jobs, this need can only increase. Yet Congress is contemplating block granting the child care programs serving low-income families and cutting the funds by 9 percent.

Child care assistance for low-income working families is only one way of ensuring that work pays more than welfare. Also needed, Lerman notes, are health insurance, child support, and the EITC. Without these, welfare reform may satisfy the public demand that people work in return for assistance, but will move very few families out of poverty.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
ISSUE THREE: The Effect of Time Limits
Current proposals would permit states to establish their own time limits for AFDC but deny federal funds to those on welfare longer than five years. The question addressed in Chapters 7, 8, and 9 is the likely consequences of cutting off all cash assistance.

In Chapter 7, LaDonna Pavetti finds that welfare recipients often leave the rolls within a year or two but many return almost as quickly. Looked at over a lifetime (that can include multiple spells), 42 percent end up receiving benefits for less than two years. Only 35 percent stay on for more than five years. Because these long-stayers accumulate on the rolls, however, 76 percent of current recipients are in the midst of a five-year or longer stay. Moreover, these long-stayers are a particularly disadvantaged group. Half enter AFDC with no work experience and 63 percent have less than a high school education.

In Chapter 8, Sheila Zedlewski and I estimate the effects of the PRA on welfare caseloads and costs and assess how states and individuals are likely to respond. We find that if the PRA were fully in effect, about 42 percent of the current caseload would lose their eligibility (primarily because of the time limit) and another 30 percent would receive lower benefits. (Because the new rules would be phased in gradually, not all these effects would occur immediately.) As eligibility and benefits were cut, federal and state welfare costs would shrink commensurately. But it would take time for these savings to materialize. In the shorter run, states would have to use their own resources to finance any growth in the caseload induced by a recession or demographic trends, as well as any expenses associated with moving people into jobs. These estimates of the effects of the PRA assume no changes in individual or state behavior, both of which are likely in response to the federal policy and budget changes now under consideration. Individuals are likely to work more under the threat of a benefit cutoff, while states are likely to spend less under a fixed block grant, with ultimate effects that are difficult to predict.

A more critical issue is what happens to recipients who lose all eligibility for welfare as the result of a federal or state time limit. Sandra and Sheldon Danziger argue in Chapter 9 that many recipients reaching a time limit will seek but not find steady employment. They base this conclusion on a number of studies of the low-wage labor market, but particularly on the experiences of former recipients of General Assistance in Michigan, a program the state terminated in 1991. Looking at the principal source of cash support received by this group two years later, they find that only 20 percent were employed in a formal job while another 17 percent held casual jobs. More than a third had found their way onto other benefit programs (most frequently disability benefits), and the remainder were relying on family or friends or had no known source of income. Looking just at a subsample of this group with characteristics similar to those on AFDC, the Danzigers find that 46 percent of them were employed if they had at least a high school degree and 28 percent if they did not. Combined with Pavetti's evidence on the characteristics of long-stayers, this suggests that only about one-third of welfare recipients who lose assistance after five years are likely to be employed two years later.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
ISSUE FOUR: Preventing Dependency
Precisely because it is so difficult to make welfare recipients self-sufficient, there is a growing consensus that more effort should be devoted to preventing dependency in the first place. This means paying attention to a wide range of issues, including declining job prospects for the unskilled (especially men) and widespread deficiencies in the education system. However, two problems believed to be closely linked to welfare dependency have received special attention: rising rates of out-of-wedlock childbearing, especially among teenagers, and low levels of child support from the fathers of children on AFDC.

In Chapter 10, Freya Sonenstein and Gregory Acs note that the teenage birth rate declined steadily during the 1960s and 1970s, leveled off in the first half of the 1980s, and increased again starting in 1986. Rising rates of sexual activity throughout this period exposed a larger and larger proportion of adolescents to the risk of pregnancy. At the same time, greater use of contraception and abortion kept the birth rate trending downward until the mid-1980s. Since then abortion rates have fallen, and this together with a shift in the composition of the teenage population toward demographic groups with higher fertility rates, such as Hispanics, appears to explain the post-1986 rise.

Contrary to conventional wisdom, teenagers are not a large part of the AFDC caseload. Moreover, among those on welfare, few establish separate households; most live with their parents. In 1992, only 8 percent of the AFDC caseload consisted of women under the age of 20, and for women under 18, only 18 percent lived alone with their children. But the majority of mothers on AFDC (52 percent) had their first child as a teenager, and research has implicated early childbearing as one factor predicting subsequent poverty and welfare dependency.

While the teenage birth rate is now lower than it was in the 1960s, the proportion of such births that occur outside of marriage has increased dramatically. In Chapter 11, Acs takes up the question of whether welfare induces women to have children outside of marriage. (Out-of-wedlock childbearing, it should be noted, is not confined just to teenagers. In fact, in 1992, only 30 percent of all nonmarital births were to women under the age of 20.)

Acs notes that, in inflation-adjusted terms, welfare benefits have been declining at the same time that out-of-wedlock childbearing has been increasing. Moreover, there is little correlation between the generosity of the welfare system in a state and its nonmarital birth rate, even after adjusting for factors that might otherwise obscure welfare's true effect. Some studies find an association between welfare benefit levels and nonmarital births among whites. But the overall impression from all the studies so far, using a range of data and methodologies, is that welfare has, at most, a small influence on out-of-wedlock childbearing 6.

In the end, as Acs notes, one cannot confidently extrapolate from this body of research which has examined the effects of relatively small variations in welfare benefits on behavior to predict the consequences of the major changes now under consideration. Further, both he and Sonenstein suggest that welfare is much less likely to affect sexual behavior than it is to affect the decision to have an abortion or to marry, once pregnant. Thus, welfare reform proposals that deny benefits to young unwed mothers, or cap benefits for those who have additional children on welfare, are more likely to affect abortion or marriage than pregnancy itself.

Marriage is only one way to bring fathers back into the picture. Requiring that they pay child support is another. In Chapter 12, Elaine Sorensen reviews the potential of this strategy to reduce poverty and welfare dependency. Under an ideal child support system defined here as one that uses the Wisconsin child support guidelines and collects all child support in full an additional $34 billion could have been collected in 1990. Almost three-fifths of this uncollected child support results from not having a child support award in place (often because paternity is not established). The remainder is due to inadequate or uncollected awards.

Not all of this $34 billion in potential child support would go to the children of those on welfare (or to the governments that support them). Many of the fathers of these AFDC children are themselves poor and would not be expected to pay much, if any, child support. Sorensen estimates that perhaps 13 to 26 percent of all noncustodial fathers are in this unable-to-pay category. In addition, a lot of uncollected child support is owed to children who are not poor and not on AFDC. For these reasons, the potential of a better child support system to reduce poverty and welfare dependency is not as great as the $34 billion figure might imply.

Nonetheless, Sorensen estimates that, had an ideal child support system been in place in 1989, the number of poor individuals would have dropped by 1.4 million (5 percent), the number of families on welfare by 400,000 (9 percent), and welfare costs by $5 billion (9 percent) 7.

Although $5 billion in savings is small in comparison to the $34 billion in uncollected support, it is large relative to the annual savings associated with recently proposed reforms such as the PRA, which entails savings of no more than $2.6 billion in the fifth year after enactment. Moreover, the savings due to increased child support are achieved not by placing new burdens on poor mothers, but by requiring those who can afford it to support their children.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Welfare Reform: An Analysis of the Issues
ISSUE FIVE: The Broader Safety Net
When people talk about welfare reform they usually focus primarily on the AFDC program. But the current safety net is much broader than this and includes food stamps, SSI, Medicaid, and a number of smaller programs. The final three chapters analyze the proposed changes in some of these other low-income programs 8.

In Chapter 13, James Ohls notes that the Food Stamp program, which now provides benefits to one out of every 11 Americans, is the ultimate safety net. Unlike any other program, it involves a federal commitment to place a floor under every income, regardless of where a person lives or in what type of household. Although its support is restricted to food assistance, its impact may be less on nutrition than on providing low-income families with a source of purchasing power. (Studies indicate that households given stamps spend somewhat more on food than those given an equivalent amount of cash, but stamps free up for other purposes resources that otherwise would have been spent on food.)

AFDC benefit levels vary widely by state. The Food Stamp program cuts this variation in half because food stamp benefits increase by 30 cents for each dollar reduction in AFDC benefits. Food stamps also help communities adjust to economic changes since they are available to more families when unemployment increases and are indexed to keep pace with inflation.

The PRA proposes to cut food stamp costs, increase state flexibility, and require more work. Cost-of-living adjustments would be reduced to 2 percent a year and the allowable shelter deduction frozen, progressively weakening the inflation protection of food stamps. States would be given flexibility to change the food stamp eligibility and benefit rules for their AFDC caseload and their total caseload, if they opted for electronic benefit transfer (EBT) instead of paper coupons. Finally, a work requirement would make able-bodied prime-age adults without dependents ineligible after three months, unless they were employed at least half time or were in a work or training program. (Only minimal funding $75 million is provided to help them find jobs.)

The proposed changes would produce five-year savings estimated at $23 billion 9. They would cut benefits (compared to the current program) by 21 percent over five years and by up to 30 percent over ten years.

As Ohls points out, in this era of budget constraints, it may be reasonable to include the Food Stamp program in the search for cost savings, more work effort, and greater flexibility for the states. But it is not necessary to remove the entitlement status of the Food Stamp program or federal responsibility for eligibility and benefit standards in order to achieve these objectives.

In Chapter 14, Pamela Loprest examines proposed changes in the SSI program for children with disabilities. The number of children receiving SSI has more than doubled over the past five years. The reasons are not fully understood but include court cases and administrative changes that have liberalized eligibility along with aggressive outreach. Press accounts have suggested that some of the growth also may be due to fraud and abuse for example, parents coaching children to "act crazy" in order to make them eligible. The Social Security Administration has found no clear evidence of such abuses. All in all, though, many experts and policymakers believe that some tightening of the eligibility rules is needed, and Congress established a Childhood Disability Commission in 1994 to review the current situation and recommend reforms. In the meantime, the PRA has called for a dramatic restructuring of SSI without the benefit of such a review. If enacted, the PRA would deny cash assistance to most of the disabled children in low-income families who now receive it. Instead, the bulk of them would be eligible for Medicaid and for services to be funded by block grants to the states. Of all new applicants who would be eligible for cash benefits under current rules, 21 percent would continue to receive these benefits (on the grounds that they are institutionalized or at risk of becoming so), 61 percent would receive block grant services, and 18 percent would be ineligible for either cash or services (because they do not have a specific, medically listed disability).

Many other approaches to reforming SSI for children are possible. The choice depends on a fuller understanding, and agreement among professionals in the field, of what constitutes a disability and on the overall objectives and philosophy of the program. Some believe SSI should continue to provide cash benefits to low-income families who have the additional burden of caring for a disabled child; others believe it should focus on providing just the specific medical care or other special services needed by the children themselves as a result of their disabling condition.

Chapter 15 by Michael Fix and Wendy Zimmermann turns to the question of what benefits should be made available to immigrants. As they note, illegal immigrants are currently ineligible for all benefits with the exception of emergency medical care, child nutrition, and education. Legal immigrants, in contrast, have traditionally been eligible for most benefits on the grounds that they pay taxes, can be drafted in time of war, and should be as fully integrated into American society as possible. It is also argued that making citizenship the gateway to receipt of benefits would induce many people to seek it simply to qualify for benefits and place a substantial administrative burden on an already hard-pressed Immigration and Naturalization Service.

The PRA would change dramatically the rules for legal immigrants by denying most of them access to AFDC, SSI, food stamps, Medicaid, and other social services. They would continue to be eligible for other means-tested programs if their sponsor's income were low enough. The effects would be concentrated in the small number of states where immigrants are concentrated New York and California in particular. These and other affected states would have to decide whether to pick up the responsibilities shed by the federal government or to pass them along to local governments and nonprofit institutions.

Fix and Zimmermann note that legal immigrants' current use of cash assistance programs is only slightly higher than that of natives and is heavily concentrated among two groups: refugees on AFDC and the elderly on SSI. They suggest that any concern about excessive use of public benefits by immigrants should focus on these two groups. They also lay out four principles (and some specific ideas) that might guide reform more generally: the need to prevent an influx of immigrants seeking to benefit from U.S. generosity; the need to promote family not government responsibility for new arrivals; the need to provide at least a temporary safety net for those who later fall on hard times; and the need to make a distinction between programs that provide income assistance and those that provide education, training, or other services that promote the integration and upward mobility of new arrivals.

4. Committee on Ways and Means, op. cit., p. 368.

5. This is a consequence of the elimination of a federal match and is likely to occur for two reasons. First, states will have uneven increases in their needy populations but will continue to get the same level of assistance from the federal government, creating drastically uneven fiscal pressures from state to state. Second, current law creates an incentive for greater welfare spending in the poorest states because the federal share of welfare spending is highest in states with low per-capita incomes. Elimination of this "progressive" matching rule is likely to widen further benefit disparities.

6. An ongoing evaluation of New Jersey's recently implemented family cap will add to our knowledge here.

7. Even these figures are an exaggeration of what a better child support system might yield since it will never be possible to establish an award and collect funds in full from every absent father.

8. Because congressional deliberations on Medicaid were only just beginning at the time these chapters were written, it was omitted from the volume. However, a new Urban Institute study finds that congressionally proposed changes in Medicaid could eliminate health coverage for between 6 and 20 percent of current beneficiaries. See John Holahan and David Liska, "The Impact of the Senate and House Budget Committees' Proposals on Medicaid Expenditures," Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute, May 18, 1995.

9. These savings are offset by new food stamp costs associated with reduced welfare benefits for some categories of recipients. The net savings (shown in figure on page 12) are $17 billion.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Chapter 1
A Block Grant Approach to Welfare Reform
by George Peterson

Current welfare reform proposals have revived debate over devolving welfare policy to the states and financing the transfer by block grants. The welfare legislation recently passed by the House would consolidate a broad array of programs into a few block grants (see Figure 1).

This block granting would:

End automatic, universal eligibility for those who meet federal program criteria, and
Allow the states to design fundamentally different programs to achieve very broadly defined national objectives.
WHAT ARE BLOCK GRANTS?
The term "block grant" carries different meanings for different protagonists. A standard block grant might:

Consolidate a number of federal categorical programs and give state (or local) officials more discretion about how to use federal funds across categories,
Fix federal allocations in advance. Future funding is not tied to changes in the number of eligible beneficiaries or payment levels, and
Reduce federal regulation and oversight. Within broad federal goals, states can spend more effort designing programs that serve their ends and less effort reporting to the federal government.
A BRIEF HISTORY
The concept of block granting is rooted in perceived defects of the categorical grant system. Proposals to combine categorical grants into broad blocks of programs began shortly after World War II, almost as soon as categorical assistance became a significant item in the federal budget. Most of the early criticism of categorical grants focused on the administrative complexity of overseeing local programs from Washington and the handcuffing of local initiative.

The Nixon New Federalism attack went further. It viewed categorical grants as the ideal instruments of Congress - "the porkiest of the pork," in one Nixon official's description - because they delivered identifiable program benefits to narrowly drawn constituencies for which members of Congress could take credit. When Nixon proposed to combine categorical grants into "special revenue sharing" that transferred program authority to the states, the administration's political science analysis was at least partly vindicated. The special revenue sharing concept was rejected by Congress in an intensely partisan debate. Only some small block grant consolidations survived.

Block grants made their greatest inroads during the Reagan presidency, with nine block grants approved by Congress, mostly in community and social programs and health services. Before Reagan, essentially all block grant proposals had contemplated increased federal funding. Reagan introduced the strategy of using block grants to cut federal spending, arguing that, once freed from federal red tape, the states could accomplish the same programmatic ends with less outlays.

Throughout the history of block grants—as shifting political alliances combined with concern over whether federal dollars were reaching the targeted populations—Congress tended to follow initial consolidation with reimposition of some programmatic restrictions.

Despite the long history of debate, block grants today constitute a small proportion of the intergovernmental budget. All block grants together accounted for less than 7 percent of federal assistance to state and local governments in 1994, down from 11.3 percent in 1980. Current proposals would increase this share to 24 percent. Several programs now proposed for block granting are much larger than anything transferred to states in the past (see Figure 2, and Figure 3).

BLOCK GRANTS VS. ENTITLEMENTS
The entitlement nature of AFDC and food stamps has long defined the United States safety net against poverty. The current consensus, however, seems to be that cash payments to welfare families should not be a lifetime entitlement. Most recent welfare reform proposals place a time limit of some kind on family eligibility. There is no consensus about food stamps. Currently, food stamps afford the final, universal safety net for poor families, with a single national eligibility standard and a single national payment standard. Indeed, the Food Stamps benefit formula reduces overall benefit disparities among states, providing higher benefits in states with lower AFDC benefit levels.

Block grants in the form proposed will make it difficult for states to maintain existing benefits in the face of recession or demographically driven poverty growth. Federal funding for cash assistance would be frozen at $15.4 billion a year for the next five years. There are provisions for a Rainy Day Fund that would allow states to borrow to supplement funding in recessionary periods (to be detailed in Welfare Reform Briefs Number 4). But federal funds are unlikely to stretch enough to absorb the number of families that ordinarily would become eligible over the period. Financially hard-pressed states will be forced to choose among using their own funds to sustain welfare programs, restricting entry, or cutting back benefits.

STATE EXPERIMENTS
House Speaker Newt Gingrich has remarked that block granting should unleash "51 state experiments" in welfare reform. How the nation will accommodate to, or learn from, these experiments, however, is not clear. Currently, if a state desires a waiver from federal regulations to introduce its own approach to welfare, it must submit to the federal government a plan for monitoring and evaluating the outcomes of this experiment. Results are then available for other states to use in designing their programs. Most governors and many federal administrators believe the current waiver process is too time-consuming. Oregon, for example, had to wait a year for its welfare and work program to be approved. Others feel that the monitoring and evaluation procedures imposed by the federal government are too costly and too rigid.

The proposed block grants run to the other extreme. There are no evaluation requirements. In fact, the AFDC replacement block grant is drawn in such a way that meaningful state comparisons may be impossible. The laboratory of federalism would be generating many welfare experiments, but no systematic evaluation of the results.

Perhaps most fundamentally, devolution of welfare to the states is likely to set off a competitive scramble to cut benefits and limit eligibility. States are already fearful of becoming "welfare magnets." As states become freer to construct their own programs, this fear is likely to escalate. The specter of migration of the poor (or, more plausibly, of the affluent in response to the costs of providing for the poor) has plagued local welfare programs from the days of the English Poor Laws. The almost inevitable outcome of such a system is spiraling parsimony, as every state scrambles to avoid becoming a welfare haven that treats the poor more generously than its neighbors.

FEDERAL RESTRICTIONS
An ideologically pure block grant would turn over essentially all program design authority to the states. The National Governors' Association has endorsed a block grant approach that would place no restrictions on the welfare replacement programs that states devise.

Federal legislation is not moving in this direction. The House bill incorporates a number of prohibitions and mandates that would limit state discretion and increase state costs. For example, requirements would mandate that states place 10 percent of the adults on welfare rolls in jobs in fiscal year 1996 and 40 percent in FY 2003. Governors have complained that meeting these requirements would be costly (in terms of state—financed job training, child care, employer wage subsidies, or other measures); some states would find it difficult to meet the targets at any cost.

Other prohibitions built into federal legislation would prohibit states from using federal funds to pay for welfare benefits to legal immigrants who are not citizens, or support unwed mothers who have children before the age of 18. These restrictions impose broad policy limits on the kinds of welfare programs states can design, though states could use their own funds to finance such programs.

BUDGET-CUTTING ROLE
Today's block grants are an instrument of budget cutting. Many of the block grants now proposed would have their federal funding levels frozen for five years without adjustment for inflation or growth in the poverty population. Others would grow much more slowly than their categorical predecessors have done. In effect, block grants shift the fiscal risks of dealing with recession and any future poverty growth to the states and, ultimately, to families.

Block grants also eliminate state matching requirements and thereby fundamentally change the financial incentives now built into the system. Under the current, open-ended matching grant structure of AFDC and Medicaid, states have theoretically had an incentive to expand benefits and coverage, because the federal government picks up a large share (between 50 percent and 80 percent, depending upon state income) of additional costs. Savings from program cutbacks are shared with the federal government in the same proportion. Under block grants, federal payments are fixed. States would enjoy 100 percent of any program savings they generate. The change in incentives should have substantial impact. When the open-ended matching program for social services was capped and converted to a block grant, rapid state spending growth was halted almost overnight.

ADMINISTRATIVE SAVINGS
In theory, block grant expenditure reductions are compensated by administrative savings, so that the impact on beneficiaries is muted. But state "administrative" savings from previous block grants have proved difficult to isolate. States have cut back on reporting to the federal government and, often, on program monitoring. This has yielded monetary savings. Program debate often suggests that administrative savings on the order of 15 to 20 percent will be possible, but follow-up studies have found highly variable savings that administrators claim rarely exceed 5 percent. Larger savings require using the new administrative flexibility to eliminate program features or cut back coverage—i.e., real program reductions. Still, savings of even 5 percent in the welfare area can generate substantial sums of money—around $1 billion nationwide, based on the $28 billion a year currently spent by federal and state governments on AFDC.

CONSISTENCY OF REFORM
It is tempting to compromise between different approaches to welfare reform by simply block granting some programs, like AFDC, while leaving others, like Food Stamps, as open-ended federally defined entitlements. There is a danger to this approach, however. It encourages states to cut back still further on welfare programs, confident that federal Food Stamps will absorb part of the reductions. This process increases federal budget costs, and makes federal spending a captive of state calculations as to how to most effectively shift spending burdens to the one remaining entitlement program.

THE REAL CHOICE
The welfare debate has developed in a manner that identifies block grants and state choice as the only alternatives to the status quo. This oversimplifies the real choice. Congress and the President must decide, first, what national principles will guide the nation's anti-poverty policy and which programs, if any, should remain national entitlements. The current set of block grant proposals incorporates a particular view of the national interest in welfare programs—one that emphasizes limiting federal budgetary exposure.

Chapter 2
State Response to Welfare Reform: A Race to the Bottom?
by Paul Peterson

The House of Representatives approved legislation in the spring of 1995 that would eliminate Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) as an entitlement. In its place, the House bill gives each state a block grant equal to the AFDC funds the state received in the 1994 fiscal year. The terms of the block grant allow each state to set—within very limited guidelines—its own eligibility standards and benefit levels.

Such a dramatic shift in policy, if approved by the Senate and signed by the President, is likely to prove unworkable and short-lived, simply because such alterations run at odds with the underlying structure of the federal system. If welfare policy is permanently turned over to the lower tiers of government, states will find themselves in a "race to the bottom"—a race to cut welfare benefits faster than their neighbors, thereby endangering the well-being of the most marginal members of society, including large numbers of children living in poverty.

THE UPS AND DOWNS OF STATE WELFARE POLICY
Welfare policy was first formulated at the state level. AFDC itself owes its origins to state-run "mother's pensions" programs first set up in 1911 in Illinois and Missouri, long before the federal government incorporated family assistance into the Social Security Act of 1935. Because AFDC evolved out of state-operated programs, it always has been jointly financed by federal and state governments. States still retain full authority to set the AFDC benefit level and still determine many eligibility requirements.

Initially, state control did not preclude a steady rise in welfare benefits. The mean benefit paid to a family in the average state climbed (in 1993 dollars) from $306 in 1940 to $429 in 1950, $520 in 1960, and $605 in 1970. State AFDC policies began to change around 1970, a retreat that has accelerated with time. Even by 1975 the mean cash benefit in the average state had slipped to $512; by 1993 it had reached its postwar nadir of $349. All in all, the cuts between 1970 and 1993 amounted to no less than 42 percent.

In 1988, the Family Support Act explicitly gave states additional opportunities to experiment with AFDC. In keeping with a growing conservative mood at the state level, the first three major proposals submitted to the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services all proposed new restrictions on welfare. California proposed an immediate 25 percent reduction in benefits, a further reduction for all families remaining on welfare after six months, and a limit on benefit levels for new arrivals to the state to the level they were receiving in their previous state of residence. Wisconsin and New Jersey petitioned, among other things, to withhold the increase in benefits that typically came with the birth of an additional child. What began in a few states soon spread nationwide, and by now a majority of states have used the flexibility available under the 1988 legislation to restrict further AFDC eligibility and benefits.

These reductions in welfare benefits hardly can be attributed simply to newly conservative state political climates. Statistical studies indicate that it made little difference to benefit levels whether control of state legislatures was in the hands of Republicans or Democrats. For much of the period, Democrats controlled at least part of state government in most states, and in a substantial number they controlled both houses of the state legislature as well as the gubernatorial chair.

More important than politics was the increasing integration of the national economy. Capital, entrepreneurial activity, and labor have become more mobile, making states increasingly sensitive to the economic consequences of their policies1. Today, 17 percent of the population changes residence each year, and 3 percent moves across state lines. States and localities can no longer make policy choices as if they are acting in isolation. The decisions they make are noticed by people elsewhere, and the impact on their economic and fiscal situation will be felt sooner rather than later. The result is that state officials are growing ever more reluctant to provide for the needy within their jurisdictions.

THE WELFARE MAGNET
States whose welfare benefits remain relatively high have become welfare magnets - places that attract poor people because they offer higher cash benefits than do many other states. The higher the benefit, the more magnetic the state—both by keeping poor people from moving elsewhere and by attracting additional poor people into the state. The lower the benefit, the more repellent the state is to poor people—both by encouraging poor residents to leave and by deterring other poor people from moving to the state. Low-income, welfare-dependent families move at least as frequently as other demographic groups2.

The welfare magnet is a function of the great variation in welfare benefit levels among states. In 1991 the maximum annual combined cash and food stamp benefit for a family of four varied between $5,952 in Mississippi and $11,898 in California. The variation in cash benefits was even greater in 1990 than it had been in 1940. Although the food stamp benefit reduces interstate variation considerably, interstate variation in combined cash and food stamp benefits remains much greater than interstate variation in the cost of living.

Before 1970, welfare policies had little magnetic effect. Numerous state laws and administrative practices designed to impede access to the welfare system made it inadvisable to change residences merely to improve one's welfare opportunities. Among the many restrictive practices was a rule, applied by many states, denying welfare benefits to poor families for a full year if they moved into the state from beyond state borders. Thus, before 1969, the states could increase their welfare benefits without becoming a more attractive place to live for poor people in other parts of the country.

In 1969 the Supreme Court ruled that the denial to newcomers of welfare benefits granted to longer-term residents in the state of New York violated the Fourteenth Amendment's requirement that states provide citizens equal protection before the law. This decision, together with the liberalization of numerous other state administrative practices, facilitated access to the welfare rolls, especially for those moving from one state to another.

But even as court decisions were forcing states to liberalize their newcomers' access to AFDC benefits, state officials became increasingly concerned about their states becoming welfare magnets. Their concerns seem to have been well placed.

Between 1971 and 1985 the size of the low-income population increased somewhat more rapidly in states with higher benefit levels. Though modest, the magnet effect remains noticeable even when differences in economic conditions among the states are taken into account3.

Fearful of becoming welfare magnets, many states have cut their welfare benefits. The governor of Wisconsin openly worries about the influx of poor people from Illinois, which has lower welfare benefits. Policymakers in New Hampshire are currently rushing to pass a welfare "reform" for fear that recent benefit cuts in Massachusetts will induce a northward move among potential welfare recipients. In general, one finds that states with higher benefits are more likely to make deeper cuts. States also cut their welfare benefits when poverty rates are both relatively high and climbing 4.

INTENSIFYING THE RACE TO THE BOTTOM
If the House bill becomes law, the race to the bottom is almost certain to intensify. Some states will undoubtedly tighten eligibility standards and reduce benefit levels, and by so doing, reduce their share of welfare costs. If this happens, high-benefit states will become more powerful welfare magnets than ever before. Poor people in low-benefit states will consider the costs and benefits of moving to a magnet state. Some will undoubtedly decide to move, or to remain in a magnet state when they might otherwise have made a move.

Under the terms of the proposed legislation, the cost of becoming a welfare magnet will be much greater than at present. Unlike current federal welfare grants, the block grant is a fixed sum of money that does not change with the number of individuals in the state eligible for assistance. If poor people move to states with more generous benefits, those states will experience an increase in their welfare burden without any commensurate increase in federal funding. To safeguard against rapidly rising state welfare costs, the generous states will come under increasing fiscal and political pressure to reduce their benefits. Eventually, all states will be racing to shift the cost of welfare to their neighbors.

In the past, the pressure on states to cut benefits has been mitigated by the fact that increases in the cost of welfare have been shared more or less equally between states and the national government. Under the proposed legislation, new welfare costs will be borne entirely by the states. Thus, the states can be expected to react quickly to any sign they are becoming welfare magnets.

Influential members of Congress also have proposed decentralizing control over food stamps. Should such a proposal become law, variation in state policy will increase and the race to the bottom can be expected to accelerate. Until now, interstate variation in the combined cash and food stamp benefit has been moderated by the design of the Food Stamp Program, which increases by one dollar whenever cash benefits are cut by three. This provision reduces by about one-half the extent of interstate differences in combined cash and food stamp benefits. Turning the Food Stamp Program into a block grant will eliminate this important equalizing aspect of current national policy.

Should Medicaid also be incorporated into a block grant program, the problem would become even more serious. Most medical services paid for by Medicaid are mandated by federal regulations. State variation in Medicaid policy is limited largely to coverage of some optional services and the amount paid to providers for services.

Poor people in need of costly medical services have especially large incentives to locate in places where medical benefits are more generous. As the more generous states experience a rise in their low-income, medically needy populations, they will come under increasing pressure to match cuts that have occurred elsewhere. The race to the bottom could become quite deadly.

THE NEED FOR NATIONAL STANDARDS
Congress can mitigate the race to the bottom in any block grant it enacts by tying federal grants to the size of the eligible population and by setting minimum-eligibility and benefit-level standards for health care, nutrition, and cash benefits. In a society in which both people and businesses are highly mobile, it makes little sense to leave the marginal cost of welfare provision to lower tiers of government.

Paul E. Peterson is Henry Lee Shattuck Professor of Government at Harvard University and is the director of Harvard's Center for American Political Studies.

This paper revises an excerpt from a just-completed study sponsored by the Twentieth Century Fund, "The Price of Federalism," by Paul E. Peterson (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1995).

1. Timothy J. Bartik, Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? (Kalamazoo, Mich.: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1991), and Paul Brace, State Government and Economic Performance (Johns Hopkins Press, 1993).

2. Paul E. Peterson and Mark Rom, Welfare Magnets: A New Case for a National Standard (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1990).

3. After five years, a state with welfare benefits one standard deviation above the mean will have, all else being equal, a poverty rate 0.9 percent higher than a state with welfare benefits one standard deviation below the mean, according to The Price of Federalism, by Paul E. Peterson (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1995) and Peterson and Rom, 1990. Similar effects are reported in "The Impact of State Economic Differentials on Household Welfare and Labor Force Behavior," by Rebecca M. Blank, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 18, October 1995, pp. 25-58; "Migration and Income Redistribution Responsibilities," by Edward M. Gramlich and Deborah S. Laren, Journal of Human Resources, vol. 19, fall 1984, pp. 489-511; and "Public Welfare Programs and Recipient Migration," by Lawrence Southwick, Jr., Southern Economic Journal, vol. 40, October 1991, pp. 22-32.

4. In Peterson and Rom, 1990, and Peterson, 1995.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Chapter 3
Rainy Day Funds: Contingency Funding for Welfare Block Grants
by Wayne Vroman

The House-passed welfare reform bill (H.R.4) proposes to convert the present funding of Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) and other welfare programs to block grants. Each state would receive a federal allocation fixed in advance. The block grant approach to welfare has been criticized as being unresponsive to changes in economic circumstances. During an economic downturn, for example, welfare caseloads grow. A fixed federal allocation would present states experiencing such downturns with three unpleasant alternatives: reducing support levels, restricting eligibility, or adding supplemental funding out of state funds. But the House bill would also establish special "rainy day" funds to help meet such unanticipated or emergency funding needs.

WHAT ARE RAINY DAY FUNDS?
The Federal Rainy Day Fund would be established with a $1 billion appropriation in FY 1996. States could borrow from the fund for up to three years at the market interest rate for federal debt of the same maturity. The maximum permissible amount would be either $100 million or half the state's block grant for that fiscal year, whichever is smaller. To be eligible to borrow, a state must have a high and rising unemployment rate. Specifically, its unemployment rate must average at least 6.5 percent for three consecutive months and be at least 10 percent higher than the rate during the same three-month period in at least one of the previous two years.

A second, state-level rainy day fund is also authorized in the bill. States may use unexpended block grant monies in an unrestricted manner if they accumulate balances of sufficient size. Since the basic block grants will be smaller than present federal funding of AFDC, it seems unlikely states will be able to accumulate balances large enough to allow such unrestricted use. Nevertheless, this provision provides states with a financial incentive to cut AFDC payments.

HOW BIG A FUND IS NEEDED?
The appropriate size of a federal emergency or rainy day fund depends on its purpose. If the fund is intended primarily to alleviate the costs of caseload growth arising from increases in the unemployment rate, the fund does not have to be as large as if it were to serve a broader purpose.

To Compensate for Increases in Unemployment. Single-parent AFDC caseloads are not very sensitive to economic cycles. The AFDC-Unemployed Parent (AFDC-UP) caseloads are, naturally, much more sensitive to unemployment, but the AFDC-UP program accounts for only 6 to 8 percent of the total AFDC caseload. A one percentage point increase in the employment gap (the percent by which actual employment falls below full employment) raises basic AFDC caseloads by about 60,000 and AFDC-UP caseloads by 19,000. The implied peak-to-trough increases in caseloads during the 1989-1992 period were about 300,000 for basic AFDC and 95,000 for AFDC-UP. These increases represent about 8 percent and 50 percent, respectively, of the 1989 caseload levels. The combined increase of 395,000 caseloads for basic AFDC and AFDC-UP represents 10.5 percent of the total 1989 AFDC program 1.

Even if the cyclical caseload growth were double these estimates, such growth is still small relative to the experiences of the regular Unemployment Insurance (UI) program, which provides compensation for up to 26 weeks of unemployment. Between 1973 and 1975, the total number of weeks of compensation paid in the regular UI program increased by 144 percent - from 71 million to 173 million weeks. During the most recent downturn, which was less severe than that of 1973-1975, the total number of UI weeks of compensation rose by 53 percent - from 98 million weeks in 1989 to 150 million in 1992.

Combined state and federal payments for AFDC currently total about $25 billion annually. Thus, a rainy day fund that equaled 20 percent of current annual outlays would amount to $5 billion, about five times the size of the fund proposed in H.R.4.

To Compensate for Demographic or Other Change. The largest single factor affecting AFDC caseload growth is demographic change: changes in population, in the number of families headed by women, and especially in the number of families headed by never-married women. If the goal of the rainy day fund is to protect against contingencies that are broader than one year of recession-induced unemployment—such as demographic change, tightened eligibility for related safety net programs, or a recession with effects that extend beyond the one-year borrowing window - an even larger fund would be needed 2.

H.R.4 includes a provision for population growth to effect an increase in a state's basic block grant during fiscal years 1997-2000. However, the total amount specified for population growth is only $100 million. If AFDC spending were to grow in line with the kind of population growth the U.S. has experienced during recent years, it would need to increase by about 5 percent over the next five years. Instead, the $100 million included in H.R.4 equals about 0.7 percent of federal AFDC outlays.

States with large population increases would also be disproportionately affected. For example, if California accounted for one-quarter of national population growth, its basic block grant would increase by $25 million, which is only 0.5 percent of its current (federal plus state) AFDC outlays. Also, there is no explicit provision in H.R.4 for growth in the number of female-headed families, a segment which grew by 2.3 percent annually between 1987 and 1991.

Another disproportionate constraint on fund use by large states is the absolute loan cap, also set at $100 million. At present, annual AFDC spending totals about $5 billion in California, $2.5 billion in New York, and between $0.8 billion and $1.3 billion in the six next largest states. Thus the $100 million loan cap represents 2 percent, 4 percent, and 8 to 12 percent, respectively, of current annual outlays for these states. Put another way, the cap amounts to less than 20 percent of the annual AFDC spending for all the 10 states with the largest AFDC outlays. But since these 10 states account for 60 percent of total AFDC spending, the loan cap disproportionately works to the disadvantage of the large states.

ISSUES IN FUND MANAGEMENT
At least three questions are pertinent to fund management.

What should be the withdrawal criteria? If increased unemployment were the only withdrawal criterion it would be easy to review, approve, and determine loan amounts. The current eligibility criteria for H.R.4 are simple; the only problem is the possibility of false signals from unemployment rates in very small states. States would undoubtedly like to add additional criteria to recognize special circumstances, but these would complicate the approval of financial assistance.
Should withdrawals be treated as loans or grants? If funds were disbursed as grants there would be no need for the states to repay them. Grants are the more expensive route for the federal budget. But a strong case can be made for grants, since states should not be held responsible for caseload growth caused by fluctuations in the economy.

One effect of treating disbursements as loans would be that states might restrict eligibility for benefits to prevent and/or reduce their future borrowing. This was the experience of debtor state UI programs in the mid-1980s. As debtor states faced the prospect of large debt repayment costs, they enacted solvency legislation that restricted benefit availability (and raised employer UI payroll taxes).
Should the risks be pooled? A federal rainy day fund has one clear advantage over the current set of state UI trust funds—the pooling of risk. The UI programs have individual state trust funds. Since UI borrowing patterns in each recession are highly concentrated by geographic area, a system of separate funds requires the aggregate of state UI trust fund balances to be larger than what would be needed by a single national fund. With just a single nationwide AFDC fund, state-level unemployment-related risks would be pooled, and the aggregate fund would need to be only large enough for use by states with unemployment levels higher than the threshold.
HOW WOULD THE FUND INITIALLY ACQUIRE ASSETS?
The $1 billion trust fund proposed in H.R.4 would not be difficult to fund fully. But funding a new federal trust fund on a scale commensurate with the potential need - $5 billion for one-year countercyclical goals, considerably more for broader contingencies - will not be easy, particularly if it is to be accomplished within a single year. This suggests the wisdom of considering a phase-in period. The risk of a phase-in, of course, is that the next recession will start before the fund is fully built up.

The initial experiences of the UI trust funds are instructive in this respect. The UI payroll taxes were first levied in 1937. Benefits were paid beginning in 1938. From 1938 to 1945, UI taxes exceeded benefit payouts by wide margins in every year, both because the program proved less expensive than originally anticipated and because of the strong labor markets created by World War II. At the end of 1945, for example, the aggregate trust fund balance of $6.9 billion represented about seven years of benefit payouts at prevailing payout rates. The current fiscal environment would be extremely hostile, however, to such a steady and substantial initial accumulation in an AFDC rainy day fund.

DOES THERE NEED TO BE AN EXPLICIT TRUST FUND?
An alternative strategy for providing back-up to the states would be to create a federal loan authority from which eligible states could borrow during emergency periods. One advantage of this approach is that monies would not have to be set aside during the initial years of the new AFDC financing arrangement to stock the rainy day fund.

Recent experiences with the Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC) program suggest, however, that Congress is reluctant to use emergency financing (allowed under existing budget rules) even for a program as popular as jobless benefits. Four of the five phases of EUC were "financed" or fully offset, despite the program's title and its recession-related origin. Even if AFDC emergency loans had to be financed, of course, the short-run advantage would be not having to prefund the rainy day fund as proposed in H.R.4.

A CAVEAT FROM THE UI EXPERIENCE
The UI experience makes it absolutely clear that states are extremely responsive to the financing provisions of contingency funds. Before 1982, states were not charged interest for withdrawals from the federal UI loan fund. They repaid much more promptly when interest payments were assessed starting in that year. In 1983, states with UI debts were extended easier repayment terms if they restricted UI eligibility. Eligibility restrictions quickly followed. If states become responsible for cyclical AFDC costs, they are almost certain to enact benefit restrictions during economic downturns. This timing is inappropriate in both macroeconomic and human terms, but state-level fiscal considerations could easily override other priorities.

Wayne Vroman is an economist at the Urban Institute.

Related Reading:

Unemployment Insurance Trust Fund Adequacy in the 1990s, by Wayne Vroman, Upjohn Institute, 1990.

"Forecasting AFDC Caseloads with an Emphasis on Economic Factors," by Janice Peskin, "CBO Staff Memorandum," Congressional Budget Office, July 1993.

1. Janice Peskin, "Forecasting AFDC Caseloads with an Emphasis on Economic Factors," CBO Staff Memorandum (Washington, D.C.: Congressional Budget Office, July 1993). The estimates for both AFDC program components are based on the sum of all lagged coefficients and presume that the employment ratio fell by 5 percentage points between 1989 and 1992. The decline during 1973-75 was more severe than during 1989-1992 (roughly 7 percentage points in the employment ratio). This size change would increase the two AFDC components respectively by 420,000 and 131,000, for a total AFDC caseload increase of 551,000, or 14.5 percent of the 1989 caseload.

2. Legislative changes in AFDC eligibility criteria and benefit levels can also affect AFDC costs in the short run, but this source of cost changes can be controlled by the states. Cost changes from this source should not be reimbursed by a rainy day fund.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Chapter 4
Increasing the Employment and Earnings of Welfare Recipients
by Robert Lerman

Over the last three decades, political leaders and policymakers have relied on a combination of three tools to increase the employment and earnings of welfare recipients: financial incentives; job search and work requirements; and training and education. The evidence indicates that all three strategies can increase work effort. But programs that emphasize job search and work are more cost-effective than programs that rely primarily on financial incentives or training and education. By themselves, such measures are unlikely to have a major impact on poverty and welfare dependency. But as part of a more comprehensive package that includes child support, earned income tax credits, and health insurance, they could substantially improve the lives of those now on welfare.

WORK INCENTIVES
The current welfare system contains major disincentives to work. If a mother and child on Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) have no income of their own, they may qualify for an average of $500 a month in cash benefits. If that mother takes a part-time job, say at $300 a month, her family becomes "less needy" and her welfare check is reduced (to offset the increase in her income). The higher the benefit reduction rate (equivalent to a tax on earnings), the weaker the incentive to work. This incentive is further weakened because other earnings benefits (notably food stamps, housing assistance, and Medicaid) are also reduced as earnings increase 1. The policy problem is that lowering the benefit reduction rate necessarily raises the income cutoff for eligibility, increases the proportion of benefits going to the less needy, and increases the number of recipients and thus welfare expenditures.

For example, a state providing an income floor of $500 that reduced its benefit reduction rate from 100 percent (no net increase in income from earnings) to 50 percent would suddenly find its eligibility cutoff point increasing from $500 to $1,000.

The federal government began mandating states to provide some financial incentive for mothers to work in the late 1960s. During the 1970s, AFDC benefit reduction rates declined and some earnings that went to pay work expenses did not count against benefits. In 1981, however, Congress again increased the work disincentives built into AFDC and limited any earnings exclusions to the first four months on welfare.

The Clinton Administration philosophy is to "make work pay" by expanding nonwelfare benefits for recipients willing to work. In 1994, Congress passed an extremely large expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) to improve the work incentives of all families with children, including families on welfare. By 1996, for families with two or more children, the EITC will pay 40 percent of earnings up to $8,900 per year, or a maximum of $3,560. The EITC will begin to phase out as families earn more than $11,620 per year, with each $100 of added earnings lowering the EITC payment by $21. Outlays on EITC will reach $25 billion in 1996.

Expanding health insurance, child care, and child support are three other components of the strategy of making work pay outside the welfare system. At the same time, some states are experimenting with provisions that disregard increasing amounts of an AFDC recipient's earnings and thus lower the rate of benefit reduction within the AFDC program.

The Child Assistance Program (CAP) experiment in three New York counties provides new evidence that AFDC recipients respond to work incentives 2. CAP experimented with a benefit formula that combined a basic benefit lower than AFDC with a significantly more generous treatment of earnings (up to the poverty line, $1 of added earnings reduced the CAP grant by only 10 cents, a 10 percent benefit reduction rate). AFDC recipients were randomly assigned to a treatment group with access to CAP or to a control group. To qualify for the CAP rate, mothers had to have a support order for each child. During the second year of the experiment, the CAP treatment group earned 30 percent more per month than the control group. Among those initially not working, the earnings advantage of the treatment group over the control group reached 40 percent, for an average earnings gain of about $50 per month 3. Although the CAP results are encouraging, it should be noted that the program combines a lower benefit reduction rate with a lower basic benefit. It would be a mistake to conclude that lowering the benefit reduction rate by itself will necessarily lead to more employment. While those already on welfare will almost certainly work more, those made newly eligible by a higher eligibility cutoff point are likely to work less. On balance, the net effect is uncertain and may not be positive 4. Thus, the introduction of work incentives in the late 1960s and their virtual elimination in the early 1980s had less impact on employment than many people expected.

One factor that discourages many welfare recipients from working is their fear of losing health insurance coverage. According to one study, making generous health insurance benefits available to all female workers would raise the employment rate of all heads of families 16 percentage points and reduce AFDC caseloads by 20 to 25 percent 5.

In sum, although welfare recipients face high penalties on added earnings that discourage work, eliminating such disincentives extends eligibility for welfare to a larger population, reduces the work effort of people who join the rolls because of the increased income eligibility cutoff, and may not be cost effective for these reasons.

WORK REGISTRATION, JOB SEARCH, AND WORKFARE
A second strategy to increase employment is to require AFDC recipients to work or register for work and training. In 1981, amendments to the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act allowed states to use workfare. Workfare requires recipients to work in unpaid jobs in return for their welfare benefits. States responded by expanding job-search and workfare activities and making the activities mandatory. A common program began by assisting recipients with a job search in the private sector, but required unpaid work in the public sector for those unable to find private jobs.

Research using treatment-control experimental designs yielded a robust array of findings about the impacts of workfare. For a modest investment of government funds, nearly all the state and local programs evaluated have increased the earnings of recipients and reduced welfare payments 6. In many cases, the decline in welfare payments over a three- to five-year period more than offset spending by the government. For example, total AFDC payments over five years declined by 10 percent in San Diego, California, and by 14 percent in Arkansas. Most of the gain in earnings occurred because recipients subject to the mandates found jobs more quickly than their control group counterparts. However, the effects on earnings generally continued for four to five years, as a somewhat higher share of treatment group recipients decided to remain in low-wage jobs rather than leave employment completely.

The largest impacts took place in Riverside, California, where local program officials successfully imbued staff with an ethic that emphasized immediate entry into private-sector jobs 7. Case managers were subject to job placement standards and the program made great effort to persuade local employers to hire recipients. Over three years, Riverside recipients subject to the experimental treatment earned an astounding 40 to 50 percent more than recipients in the control group. Earnings gains averaged about $1,000 per year and showed no tendency to decline over time. This accomplishment is particularly impressive given the modest added costs of the Riverside intervention (about $1,600 per recipient subject to treatment) nearly all of which went for orientation, job search, and basic education. San Diego, which used a similar strategy, obtained similar results 8.

It is unclear whether other cities will be able to replicate the substantial earnings gains among welfare recipients that were achieved in these two California cities. However, the best evidence suggests that where cities or counties are willing to implement rigorous programs emphasizing job search and enforcing work requirements, about 5 to 8 percent more recipients will be working and the average earnings of welfare recipients will rise by $500 to $1,000 a year, often enough to pay for the added administrative and service costs.

TRAINING AND EDUCATION PROGRAMS
Programs allocating substantial funds to education, training, and support services generally do no better and sometimes do worse than those that focus primarily on immediate job placement. For example, despite much higher outlays for education, training, and services in Alameda County, California, than in the San Diego and Riverside programs mentioned earlier, earnings gains for recipients were lower. Emphasizing training has achieved rising earnings over time in some places, but not enough to offset higher costs and lower effects in the early years. Moreover, linking training to welfare benefits carries the potential long-run drawback of creating an incentive to go on welfare just to gain access to training.

CAN WORK-ORIENTED INTERVENTIONS REDUCE POVERTY?
The evidence clearly shows that welfare system changes can raise the earnings of recipients. Both incentives and work requirements matter, but neither is a panacea for moving families off welfare and out of poverty. In Riverside, the most successful program evaluated to date, the proportion of families escaping from poverty rose by about 4 percentage points, from 15.7 percent to 19.4 percent. Earnings averaged about $3,600 a year for all members of the treatment group (including nonworkers) and about $8,000 a year for the 44.5 percent who worked in the third year.

Viewed in the context of a more comprehensive approach to reducing welfare dependency and poverty, however, work programs can play an important role. Welfare dependency and poverty would decline substantially, for example, if families now on welfare could combine annual earnings of about $8,000 per year with $2,500 to $3,000 in child support, $3,000 in EITC, and nonwelfare-related access to health insurance. These gains would not be enough to offset the increased economic hardship associated with the rising incidence of one-parent families, but they would substantially improve the lives of large numbers of American children.

Related Reading:

Five Years After: The Long-Term Effects of Welfare-to-Work Programs, by Daniel Friedlander and Gary Burtless, Russell Sage Foundation, 1995.

The New York State Child Assistance Program: Program Impacts, Costs and Benefits, by William Hamilton, Nancy Burstein, Margaret Hargreaves, David Moss, and Michael Walker, Abt Associates, July 1983.

GAIN: Benefits, Costs, and Three-Year Impacts of a Welfare-to-Work Program, by James Riccio, Daniel Friedlander, and Stephen Freeman, Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation, September 1994.

"The Twice Poverty Trap: Tax Rates Faced by AFDC Recipients," by Linda Giannarelli and C. Eugene Steuerle, Urban Institute, 1995.

Robert Lerman is director of the Human Resources Policy Center at the Urban Institute.

1. Linda Giannarelli and C. Eugene Steuerle, "The Twice Poverty Trap: Tax Rates Faced by AFDC Recipients," Urban Institute, 1995.

2. William Hamilton, Nancy Burstein, Margaret Hargreaves, David Moss, and Michael Walker, The New York State Child Assistance Program: Program Impacts, Costs and Benefits, Abt Associates, July 1983.

3. The CAP program included some other features that may have influenced earnings, but not nearly enough to account for the earnings gains made by the CAP group.

4. Robert Moffitt, "Incentive Effects of the U.S. Welfare System: A Review," Journal of Economic Literature, March 1992.

5. Robert Moffitt and Bobbie Wolfe, "The Effect of the Medicaid Program on Welfare Participation and Labor Supply," Review of Economics and Statistics, November-December 1992.

6. Daniel Friedlander and Gary Burtless, Five Years After: The Long-Term Effects of Welfare-to-Work Programs, Russell Sage Foundation, 1995.

7. For the latest, highly comprehensive report on California's Greater Avenues for Independence (GAIN) program, see James Riccio, Daniel Friedlander, and Stephen Freeman, GAIN: Benefits, Costs, and Three-Year Impacts of a Welfare-to-Work Program, Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation, September 1994.

8. A future issue of Welfare Reform Briefs by Lawrence M. Mead will cite more evidence on, and give a discussion of, this approach.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Chapter 5
An Administrative Approach to Welfare Reform
by Lawrence M. Mead

Is the best way to reform welfare to restructure it from the top, or to improve administration at the bottom? The two major proposals now on the table—the Clinton Administration's Work and Responsibility Act and the Personal Responsibility Act passed by House Republicans—emphasize restructuring.

Both proposals seek to limit government's commitments to the needy, in the view that this is the best way to discourage unwed pregnancy and nonemployment by poor adults - the chief conditions that precipitate dependency. But both proposals conflict with public desires about reform, which are to require work of employable welfare-receiving adults while continuing support for the needy.

The Clinton plan maintains support levels but exempts much of the caseload from work requirements in order to limit costs. The Republican bill includes tough work standards but provides no specific funding for work programs, and would allow families to be denied aid whether or not they could work.

REFORM AS ADMINISTRATION
A more promising approach may be to intensify the administrative style of reform that dominated welfare policy from the late 1960s through the Family Support Act (FSA) of 1988. This approach to welfare reform sought to rectify abuses and enforce work requirements while receiving welfare, without curbing eligibility or challenging the principle of aid. As a condition of federal welfare funding, states have had to:

Increase quality control, i.e., minimize errors in benefit payments in AFDC and other programs;
Improve collection of child support; and
Require employable recipients to enter work programs designed to place them in jobs or training.
All of these measures involve enforcement - demands that recipients comply with certain rules as a condition of aid.

Quality control sharply reduced the incidence of errors in AFDC, from 17 percent in 1973 to 6 percent in 1990. The potential for further savings there appears small. Child support is far less fully enforced. Only 11 percent of AFDC costs are now defrayed out of support collections. But even optimal child support enforcement would probably reduce the AFDC rolls only 9 percent, simply because the fathers of welfare families typically have very low earnings 1.

THE POTENTIAL OF WORK REQUIREMENTS
Work requirements within welfare show more potential. Only 6 percent of AFDC mothers report working at a given time. Probably a third actually work, with much of the earnings unreported to welfare offices 2, but this level is still well below that found among nonpoor single mothers, over half of whom work full-year and full-time. The best estimates are that two-thirds to four-fifths of welfare mothers potentially could work 3. If they did so "on the books," between one-third and four-fifths of them would leave AFDC and food stamps, the extent depending mainly on whether they worked full-time or part-time and also on their child support income and child care costs 4.

The Job Opportunities and Basic Skills (JOBS) program, the employment program now linked to AFDC, is a long way from enforcing work on that level. In 1995, JOBS rules require that states have 20 percent of employable recipients active in the program on a monthly basis 5. By 1993, the average state had obtained an activity level of 23 percent. In California, the program raised the earnings of clients an average of 22 percent over three years, leading to a 6 percent drop in welfare payments. In Riverside County, which had the strongest results, the comparable figures were 49 and 15 percent 6. Such limited effects on the rolls cause many analysts to conclude that the potential of work requirements, too, is limited.

However, these results may understate the potential of a determined work program to increase activity while recipients are receiving welfare assistance and to reduce such assistance over time. In the 1980s, work programs that preceded JOBS at least doubled the share of recipients engaged either in work, looking for work, or training, compared to controls 7. And though the nation suffered a sizable rise in welfare program participation in recent years, states that implemented JOBS forcefully recorded a smaller increase, even controlling for other influences 8.

THE WISCONSIN EXAMPLE
The potential of an administrative approach to reform is best shown in Wisconsin. The state has cut its caseload 23 percent since 1987. While some of the fall was due to a 6 percent benefit cut in 1987 and a favorable economy compared to the rest of the country, the state cut its caseload by 3 percent even during 1989-1993, a period when the country as a whole saw a 29 percent increase. Wisconsin achieved this despite paying the twelfth-highest welfare benefits in the nation. Only two other states recorded any reduction: Louisiana and Mississippi.

A major factor appears to be an effective JOBS program. Wisconsin ranks well above average in JOBS participation, and has recently promoted an emphasis on immediate employment (as opposed to education and training), one of the reasons for Riverside County's success. The most effective Wisconsin county programs insist that clients participate and take available jobs, and they invoke these requirements as soon as recipients enter the welfare system.

In Kenosha, the most notable case, 88 percent of the caseload is enrolled in JOBS in a typical month, and 40 percent of clients are already working while still on welfare. The employment figure is so high, in part, because the program emphasizes part-time work along with remediation. Kenosha stresses work but encourages clients to pursue training for better positions once they are employed. As a result, it achieves both high numbers of job entries and high job quality (e.g., high wages and job retention).

The effective work programs combine assistance with clear expectations of reciprocal responsibility on the part of the clients. These programs induct all employable recipients into the program, then quickly assign them to job search or, if necessary, remediation. Above all, case managers follow up on clients to make sure they fulfill their assignments. Staff also pursue dropouts to return them to the program. A work message is conveyed strongly but usually informally. Kenosha makes heavy use of "reconciliation" proceedings, for example, minimizing sanctioning of clients (financial penalties) for non-cooperation.

WHAT IT TAKES TO REFORM WELFARE
Wisconsin achieves the sort of welfare reform the public wants - more work and less dependency while maintaining aid to the needy. But this administrative style of reform makes severe demands on government. It requires strong political leadership, skilled administrative direction, hard-working staffs, and efficient reporting systems. Successful managers must set high expectations for their staffs, as well as clients, and must hold accountable for performance the agencies to which they subcontract for services. Exceptional work programs require years of development.

Wisconsin can meet those demands because the state has all of the following:

An innovative governor willing to make welfare reform his major issue. The Tommy G. Thompson administration has launched several reform initiatives of its own.
Initiative for reform at multiple levels aside from the governor's office, including a number of counties and business groups.
High-quality, well-funded bureaucracy at the state and county levels.
A bipartisan, progovernment political culture in which, more than in most states, liberals support enforcing work in welfare and conservatives support an ambitious social policy.
THE FEDERAL ROLE
Whereas the restructuring approach to reform gives priority to policy changes made in Washington, the administrative approach makes the local level primary, for it is only there that effective programs combining aid with behavioral requirements can be realized. The role for federal policymakers then changes. They must see themselves less as leading change and more as creating incentives for effective program development lower down in the intergovernmental system. They must also think in terms not only of resource distribution but also of building the type of institutions that have helped make Wisconsin's welfare reform effort so successful. Thinking in these structural terms is alien to the thoughtways of Washington.

The difficulty is that few state and local governments have institutions as strong as those of Wisconsin (or Kenosha). Most deliver public services adequately, but they lack the greater political consensus and administrative capacity required to reform the welfare system from within. Fortunately, federal policies can promote change. Federal requirements drove the sharp lowering of error rates in grant payment, just as they now, at a slower pace, are toughening child support enforcement. The participation mandates set for JOBS in the Family Support Act already have forced big-city welfare departments, such as New York's, to get serious about work for the first time.

Rather than cut or time-limit welfare, Congress should update the mandates that have prompted work enforcement to date. At a minimum, it should extend the 20 percent JOBS participation standard in effect for 1995, which is due to expire at the end of the current fiscal year. Congress might also:

Raise the JOBS participation floor to 50 percent, to be implemented over several years. Both the Clinton and Republican plans would do this, although the latter measures participation more stringently.
Set some standard for the share of JOBS participants who must be working or looking for work, the level to vary directly with the share of state population on welfare. The higher the latter proportion, the higher the share of recipients likely to be employable.
Set more specific performance measures for JOBS, for example for the number and quality of job entries achieved. Such measures were called for by the FSA in 1988, but the Clinton Administration has yet to make specific recommendations.
All of these measures would be connected in some way to federal funding, so that states would face strong financial incentives to improve the reach and quality of their programs. Exactly how they would do this would be left to them. The standards would force local authorities to give ongoing attention to the work mission, and over time the administrative capacity of welfare would rise.

Lawrence M. Mead is Professor of Politics at New York University and Weinberg Visiting Professor at the Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs at Princeton University.

1. Elaine Sorensen, "The Benefits of Increased Child Support Enforcement," Welfare Reform Briefs Number 2, Urban Institute, April 1995.

2. Kathleen Mullan Harris, "Work and Welfare among Single Mothers in Poverty," University of North Carolina, Department of Sociology, November 1992.

3. Rebecca A. Maynard, "Subsidized Employment and Non-Labor Market Alternatives for Welfare Recipients," in The Work Alternative: Welfare Reform and the Realities of the Job Market, Demetra Smith Nightingale and Robert H. Haveman, eds. (Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1995), pp. 114-115, 114 n. 2.

4. Charles Michalopoulos and Irwin Garfinkel, "Reducing the Welfare Dependence and Poverty of Single Mothers by Means of Earnings," Institute for Research on Poverty, August 1989.

5. "Employable" here includes, roughly, welfare mothers who are not disabled, whose youngest child is at least three years old, and who do not have other family members requiring care in the home.

6. James Riccio, Daniel Friedlander, and Stephen Freedman, GAIN: Benefits, Costs, and Three-Year Impacts of a Welfare-to-Work Program (New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation, September 1994).

7. Lawrence M. Mead, The New Politics of Poverty: The Nonworking Poor in America (New York: Basic Books, 1992), p. 168.

8. Lawrence M. Mead, "The New Paternalism in Action: Welfare Reform in Wisconsin," Wisconsin Policy Research Institute, January 1995, pp. 7-11.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Chapter 6
Child Care Block Grants and Welfare Reform
By Sandra Clark and Sharon Long

Recently introduced legislation would significantly alter the current system of child care assistance for low-income families. Proposed changes would consolidate the major sources of federal assistance into a single block grant to states and reduce federal funding by 9 percent over the next five years. They would also reduce cash assistance to families, thereby increasing the number of parents needing to work. Thus, welfare reform will increase the need for affordable child care at the same time as the block grant mechanism is likely to reduce available child care subsidies.

CURRENT FEDERAL CHILD CARE
Federal involvement in the child care market has been justified as a means of offsetting the cost of children, as a work incentive for low-income parents, and as an investment in the education and development of children. On these grounds, the federal government provides substantial support for child care through tax credits, direct subsidies, and supportive services.

Of the more than 20 different sources of federal support for child care, the single largest source is the nonrefundable Dependent Care Tax Credit, which offsets 20 to 30 percent of a working parent's child care expenses (up to a maximum) via the tax system, at a federal cost of $2.5 billion in 1993. Most of the 6 million families receiving this credit are middle - and upper-income, since the credit is not available to families too poor to pay taxes. One-third of working families with incomes greater than $25,000 a year claimed the tax credit in 1988, compared to 12 percent of working families with incomes below the poverty line 1.

Of greater relevance to low-income families are the four major federal direct-subsidy programs that are the focus of the block grant legislation: Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) Child Care, Transitional Child Care, At-Risk Child Care, and the Child Care and Development Block Grant (CCDBG). In FY 1993, the federal government provided $1.74 billion in funding for these four programs combined (see Figure 1).

The AFDC and Transitional Child Care programs provide child care entitlements to families who currently receive AFDC and are working or in job training programs, and families who have lost eligibility for AFDC within the last 12 months due to employment. The At-Risk Child Care program serves low-income working families who would be at risk of becoming eligible for AFDC if they did not receive child care assistance. The CCDBG, which accounts for about half the total federal spending that would be affected by the block grant, serves the broad, low-income working population. Neither the At-Risk nor the CCDBG program guarantees child care to individual families. The AFDC, Transitional, and At-Risk programs all require state matching funds; the CCDBG does not have a match requirement. Some CCDBG funds are used to provide assistance to AFDC families, thereby reducing the funds available to the non-AFDC working poor.

Program eligibility rules and provider reimbursement rates vary widely across the states, and in some cases across programs within a state. The current system often is criticized as unnecessarily fragmented because of multiple funding streams and program rules. Even in states that have effectively created child care systems that are "seamless" to the families served, the system is complex and difficult to administer.

HEAD START
While not traditionally viewed as a child care program, Head Start provides out-of-home services to a large number of low-income children. In FY 1993, Head Start received nearly $2.8 billion in federal funding and served about 714,000 low-income children.

Because Head Start was designed as a child development rather than a child care program, it has not, in general, met the child care needs of low-income working families. Historically, Head Start has served primarily 3- to 5-year-olds in part-day programs, making it an unsuitable option for low-income parents working a full day or for younger siblings of program participants. In recent years, efforts have been made to increase the number of Head Start programs offering full-day services and to expand Head Start services to children ages three and under.

DISPARITIES AMONG ELIGIBLE GROUPS
Among the various low-income groups eligible for At-Risk and CCDBG funds, state-established funding priorities often target families with special needs (e.g., teen parents, child protective services clients), leaving limited funds available to the broader low-income working population. As a result, many eligible families go unserved and programs maintain long waiting lists for child care assistance. Statewide estimates of 40,000 (Texas) to 225,000 (California) children waiting for subsidies have been reported by the General Accounting Office 2. In San Francisco, a low-income working mother can wait up to two years to receive a subsidy for a toddler and one year for an infant. Often a family's economic situation changes or a child "ages" out of a program while the family is waiting for assistance 3.

Thirty percent of working poor families, compared to between 36 and 37 percent of nonworking poor and nonpoor families, receive child care assistance from direct subsidies (including Head Start) or through the tax system (see Figure 2). The working poor are less likely than the nonworking poor to qualify for and receive child care subsidies and less likely than higher-income families to file a tax return and receive the tax credit 4.

THE PROPOSED CHILD CARE BLOCK GRANT
The Personal Responsibility Act (H.R.4) would establish a single child care block grant that consolidates the CCDBG, AFDC, Transitional, and At-Risk programs, as well as several smaller child care programs. The Dependent and Child Care Tax Credit and Head Start would be unaffected. Funding for the new child care block grant would be capped at $2.1 billion a year—$150 million above the FY 1994 federal funding level for the four major child care subsidy programs to be included. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that this change would reduce federal funding by $1 billion over the FY 1996-2000 period, a 9 percent reduction from current federal spending on the four major programs involved.

Under the block grant proposal, states would no longer be required to match federal funds. The impact of the block grants on child care funding levels is likely to vary widely across the states. But the overall reduction in child care spending is likely to be higher than the federal reduction alone, because states will have an incentive to reduce or eliminate what they now spend in matching funds for child care. When federal funding for social services (including child care) was reduced in the early 1980s, states did not, in general, provide added funds for child care services. Instead, state funds were used to maintain crisis-oriented social services 5.

IMPLICATIONS OF THE PROPOSED BLOCK GRANT
H.R.4 would grant states increased flexibility to target and administer child care subsidy dollars. This change could reduce the complexity of the current system by eliminating the multiple funding streams and program rules. However, a block grant would also eliminate all entitlements to child care assistance, leaving the total number of families served subject to the available funds. As more families participate in education and training activities and enter the work force in response to welfare reform measures, there is likely to be an increase in the number of children needing child care.

In addition, child care subsidy programs tend to encourage work. A number of studies report significant increases in mothers' employment or labor force participation associated with lower child care costs. Several recent studies provide evidence that the effects are stronger for low-income families. One such study estimates that providing a full subsidy for poor mothers would increase their labor force participation from 29 to 44 percent, compared to an increase of 43 to 57 percent for near-poor mothers, and 55 to 65 percent for nonpoor mothers 6.

Reduced child care funding is likely to lead a large number of families to rely on relatives or friends for informal child care. But this is not an option for all families - as relatives and friends may not live nearby or may be in the labor force themselves - and may be inadequate for others. Parents using informal arrangements report a greater incidence of losing time from work or being prevented from working because of child care problems than those using formal arrangements 7.

Also, informal care is not always provided free of charge. About 36 percent of employed mothers using relatives for care pay for that care 8. Overall, 27 percent of working poor families pay for care, with child care costs taking 33 percent of the family budget on average. This compares to 13 percent of the budget of nonpoor families with incomes less than $25,000 a year, and 6 percent for families with incomes of $25,000 a year or more (see Figure 3). Child care ranks as the single largest expense after housing, food, and taxes for working parents 9.

Strapped family budgets limit the funds available to pay for child care and constrain the quality of child care that can be purchased. A significant percentage of day care centers and family child care homes have been reported to provide care that impedes the emotional and intellectual growth of children 10. Such problems could be exacerbated by the proposed funding reductions.

CONCLUSION
The goal of H.R.4 and similar proposals is to move low-income families into the work force. Child care block grants may undermine efforts to achieve this goal by limiting low-income families' ability to obtain stable, dependable child care.

One of the objectives of block granting and capping programs like subsidized child care is to reduce the budget deficit. Deficit reduction is a worthy goal. But reducing child care subsidies for low-income working families - while maintaining the Dependent Care Tax Credit (used primarily by higher-income families) - concentrates the burden of deficit reduction on those least able to pay.

Sandra Clark is a research associate and Sharon Long is a senior research associate at the Urban Institute.

1. Sandra L. Hofferth, "The Impact of Welfare Reform and Work Requirements on the Demand for Child Care," testimony before the Senate Committee on Labor and Human Resources, March 1, 1995.

2. General Accounting Office, "Working Poor and Welfare Recipients Face Service Gaps," May 1994.

3. Sandra J. Clark and Sharon K. Long, "Child Care Prices: A Profile of Six Communities," Urban Institute, 1995.

4. Hofferth, 1995.

5. Madeleine H. Kimmich, America's Children: Who Cares? Urban Institute, 1985.

6. General Accounting Office, "Child Care Subsidies Increase Likelihood that Low-Income Mothers will Work," December 1994.

7. Sandra L. Hofferth et al., National Child Care Survey, 1990, Urban Institute, 1991; and Gary L. Siegel and Anthony Loman, Child Care and AFDC Recipients in Illinois: Patterns, Problems, and Needs, Institute of Applied Research, 1991.

8. Hofferth et al., 1991.

9. Committee for Economic Development, "Why Child Care Matters: Preparing Young Children for a More Productive America," 1993.

10. Suzanne Helburn et al., "Cost, Quality, and Child Outcomes in Child Care Centers: Executive Summary," Univeristy of Colorado, 1995, and Ellen Galinsky et al., "The Study of Children in Family Child Care and Relative Care," Families and Work Institute, 1994.
Chapter 7
Who is Affected by Time Limits?
By LaDonna Pavetti

The Personal Responsibility Act (H.R.4), known as the PRA, passed by the House of Representatives includes a five-year limit on the receipt of cash welfare benefits. This provision would prohibit states from using federal funds to provide cash assistance to families who have received cash assistance for 60 months or longer. In cases of extreme hardship, states would be permitted to exempt up to 10 percent of their caseloads from this restriction. The PRA does not require states to provide benefits for any minimum period of time. Thus, the proposal allows states to provide cash assistance to families for fewer than five years.

WHY TIME-LIMIT AFDC BENEFITS?
Policies to time-limit AFDC benefits have been important components of the vast majority of welfare reform proposals developed over the past year. Time limits were initially proposed as part of a comprehensive set of welfare reform policies designed to increase the economic return to recipients from working, especially in low-wage jobs, and to increase the flow of income to children through better child support enforcement. Central to this strategy was a plan to convert welfare into a transitional system designed to provide short-term financial, educational, and social support for families in need of such assistance and minimum-wage jobs for families who exhausted their transitional support. The time limit included in the Work and Responsibility Act of 1994, President Clinton's welfare reform plan, was modeled after this approach. Under the Clinton plan, AFDC recipients would have been eligible for cash assistance not conditioned on work for up to 24 months. After 24 months, families receiving assistance who were able to work but unable to find unsubsidized employment would have been eligible to continue receiving cash assistance as long as they were willing to work in exchange for that assistance.

The time limit in the PRA departs dramatically from this conception of time limits. First, the time limit is not linked to any increased efforts to help recipients find and keep unsubsidized employment. Second, the PRA provides no safety net for families who are willing to work but are unable to find unsubsidized jobs.

HOW MANY FAMILIES WOULD BE AFFECTED BY POLICIES TO TIME-LIMIT AFDC?
It is extremely common for AFDC recipients to leave the welfare rolls shortly after their initial receipt of welfare assistance. However, it is equally common for many of those who do leave to return almost as rapidly as they left. Even when this movement on and off the rolls is accounted for, the majority of families who ever receive AFDC benefits receive them for relatively short periods of time. Still, over their lifetimes, a substantial minority of families do end up receiving AFDC for extended periods of time. In addition, because these longer-term recipients accumulate on the welfare rolls as time passes, they end up accounting for a large fraction of recipients on the welfare rolls at any given point in time. Thus, a substantial number of families eventually would be affected by policies to time-limit AFDC benefits.

The data presented in Figure 1 illustrate these points. The second column shows a distribution of total time on welfare (over a lifetime) for new entrants (families just beginning a spell of welfare receipt who have never been on the rolls before). The last column shows a distribution of total time (also over a lifetime) for all recipients currently on the welfare rolls. These two distributions provide very different "pictures" of the caseload. Of all families that become dependent on welfare assistance, about 42 percent receive benefits for less than 24 months. But at any point in time, there are many more long-term recipients. For example, more than 75 percent of families on welfare at any point in time will receive welfare for more than 60 months.

Which of these two distributions is most relevant? The answer is that it depends on the policy being proposed. Legislation might conceivably specify that time limits be applied to the entire existing caseload, say by giving everyone five (more) years of eligibility as of a particular date. Or time limits might be applied just to new entrants who enroll in welfare after a particular date 1.

If the five-year time limit is applied to the entire existing caseload starting in 1996, no family would reach the time limit until at least 2001. At that point, 1.42 million families would be affected (see Figure 2). Most of them (1.34 million) were already on the rolls in 1996 but some (0.08 million) are new entrants. By 2002 the number who would reach the time limit increases to 1.65 million families (including 1.41 million who were on the rolls in 1996), and so on. Thus, over time, new entrants would begin to account for an increasing share of the AFDC caseload and families from the 1996 rolls would account for a declining proportion of the total number reaching the time limit. If only new entrants are subject to the five-year time limit, the number of families that reach it would be dramatically lower, especially in the early years of implementation (e.g. 80,000 in 2001).

EMPLOYABILITY DIFFERENCES WITHIN THE CASELOAD
The new entrant population is quite different from the population of all families on welfare, suggesting that state and local governments would have to design very different programs depending on which strategy is chosen. New entrants are likely to be younger, to have preschool-age children, and to include many who will find jobs or leave welfare without much assistance. In contrast, recipients currently on the caseload tend to be older and to have older children. Many already have received welfare for extended periods of time, and they tend to have less education and more health and other problems than new entrants. Recognizing that it would be difficult—and costly—for states to prepare successfully for permanent self-supporting employment of both young mothers just beginning their welfare receipt and older, long-term recipients, the Clinton plan only subjected recipients who were born after 1971 to a time limit (of two years rather than five).

The employability of those who would reach a five-year time limit does not look especially promising. Half of those who spend longer than five years on the welfare rolls enter AFDC with no labor market experience and 63 percent have less than a high school education (see Figure 3). Also, 42 percent first received welfare when they were under age 25, the time when the vast majority of workers make investments in education and gain experience in the labor market that prepares them for stable future employment.

EXPERIMENTS, NOT DRASTIC CHANGES, NEEDED
Undoubtedly some families faced with a time limit will find unsubsidized employment or some alternative means of support sooner than they might have without a time limit. However, the characteristics of long-term recipients shown in the table below make it extremely likely that some families will not be able to find an alternative means of support. Although we can estimate approximately how many people would be affected by the time limit proposed in H.R.4, and we know something about their characteristics, we have no way of assessing how they would fare once their welfare benefits ended. Given this uncertainty, the wisest course may be to experiment with a variety of types of time-limit provisions on a small scale, rather than implementing such a drastic policy change nationwide.

LaDonna Pavetti is a research associate at the Urban Institute.

Related Readings:

"The Dynamics of Welfare and Work," by LaDonna Pavetti, Dissertation Series #D-93-1, Malcolm Wiener Center for Social Policy, Harvard University.

Welfare Realities: From Rhetoric to Reform, by Mary Jo Bane and David Ellwood (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
Chapter 8
Assessing the Personal Responsibility Act
By Sheila Zedlewski and Isabel V. Sawhill 1

The Personal Responsibility Act (PRA) would replace the 60-year-old Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) program with block grants to the states. These block grants would fix federal payments at their 1994 levels for the next six years. States would receive grants generally in proportion to current spending and be required to spend the money on cash benefits to needy families with children; but not all needy families with children would be eligible. States would be prohibited from using federal money to provide cash assistance to:

unmarried mothers under age 18 or their children (until the mother reaches age 18);
most noncitizens;
children born while a family is receiving cash assistance; and
families who have accumulated a total of five years on assistance. 2
States also would have to pay reduced benefits to children whose paternity is not established. Finally, states would be required to have a certain proportion of their adult caseload working in either subsidized or unsubsidized jobs. This proportion would rise from 10 percent in 1996 to 50 percent by 2003. To the extent that states succeed in reducing their caseload beyond what is mandated by the new law, they could count this toward achieving the work requirement goal.

The federal mandates are designed to promote work and marriage, discourage out-of-wedlock births, and reduce long-term welfare dependency. Except for these mandates, states have broad discretion in using the block grant funds.

ESTIMATING PRA EFFECTS
The provisions contained in the PRA are likely to change as the legislation moves through Congress. Even if they were enacted as written, however, predicting state reaction is fraught with difficulty. Nonetheless, it is useful to estimate the number of families who would be affected by these provisions, assuming that (1) states maintain their current levels of financial assistance, and (2) welfare caseloads do not change significantly. We do this by applying the new PRA rules to a statistical representation of the current caseload to see how it might be affected over time. Later, we relax those assumptions to consider how states and individual recipients might react to the new rules. 3

Overall Effects
If the PRA were fully in place today, 71 percent of the current caseload would either receive reduced benefits or lose eligibility altogether. Since the PRA would not become effective fully for a number of years, however, the effects would be spread out over time (see Figure 1). Years counted toward the time limit would not begin until 1996, for example, even for those who have already been on the rolls for many years. Thus, no family would be denied assistance because of time limits until 2001, five years after the PRA takes effect.

Denial of benefits to unwed minors and noncitizens would take effect sooner. At the end of 1996, the first year of implementation, 20,000 families would lose all benefits, and more than 750,000 families would find their benefits reduced. After five years, the caseload would be reduced to slightly under four million families from its current level of nearly five million. Under full implementation, the caseload would drop to just under three million families, and an additional 1.5 million families would see their benefits reduced.

Independent Effects of Specific Provisions.
The provision elimina-ting benefits for unwed mothers under age 18 would have a small effect because these families constitute only 1 percent of the current caseload (see Figure 2).

The PRA's citizenship provisions would eliminate or reduce benefits for 6 percent of the current caseload. Only about 60,000 noncitizen families would lose all benefits, but many more families would receive reduced benefits because they include some noncitizens (for example, families with noncitizen mothers whose children are citizens).

The federal provision denying benefits to children born while the mother is on welfare would eliminate 180,000 families from the caseload, including more than two million children. Overall, about one-quarter of families that currently receive AFDC would either lose some or all of their benefits if this provision were in effect during their time on welfare.

Although the five-year time limit would have no initial effect because of the gradual phase-in, it would eventually eliminate 40 percent of the current caseload. 4 Nearly one out of every two children currently receiving cash assistance is in a family that has received benefits for at least five years.

HOW WOULD THE PRA AFFECT GOVERNMENT COSTS?
The PRA eventually would reduce total federal and state government costs. Total spending (cash assistance plus food stamps) was $37.4 billion in 1993. After full implementation, on the assumption of no caseload growth, cash and food stamp assistance together would decline to $27.4 billion (in 1993 dollars). Federally funded food stamps would increase, partially offsetting the decline in families' cash benefits. 5 But total federal and state costs for cash benefits would decline sharply, to $11.5 billion—less than the federal block grant scheduled for 1996-2000 ($14 billion annually in 1993 dollars).

Most of the government savings would not be realized until time limits go into effect five years from now (see Figure 3). In the interim, most states would likely have to spend more, not less - both to support rising costs associated with population growth, inflation, and any downturn in the economy, 6 and to fund the services needed to move recipients into jobs as mandated by the new law. 7 The only way for states to avoid spending more would be to find ways to speed up the reductions in their welfare caseloads.

HOW WOULD STATES RESPOND TO THE PRA?
Many states are likely to try to reduce benefits or caseloads even further, for at least three reasons:

Rising Fiscal Pressures.

States will face rising fiscal pressures over the next five years as a result of the capping of federal assistance under the various block grants in the PRA. Federal spending for cash assistance, nutrition, child protection, child care, and disability will be almost $70 billion less than current budget projections over this period. Thus, states will face competing pressures to spend their own limited funds on abused and neglected children, on those who are disabled, and on the other needs of low-income families. Any downturn in the economy would exacerbate these fiscal pressures on states, as will the anticipa-ted increases in the costs of Medicaid at the state level.

Repeal of Federal Matching.

Under current law, the typical state contributes 45 cents of each dollar spent on AFDC, with the federal government contributing 55 cents. Under the PRA, states would bear the full costs of any additional spending—needed, for example, to finance additional training, to maintain benefits during a recession, or to adjust benefits to offset increases in prices. Similarly, if a typical state reduces welfare benefits by one dollar under current law, it saves only 45 cents. Under the PRA it would save a full dollar, more than twice as much. Also, states could get an additional 30 cents in food stamp benefits from the federal government for every dollar reduction in welfare benefits. Thus, repeal of the matching requirement creates a strong incentive for states to cut benefits or restrict eligibility. 8

State Competition.

In the absence of a federal requirement to provide benefits to all eligible individuals, a "race to the bottom" could occur. Each state has an incentive to compete with other states in lowering its welfare spending out of fear that it will become a haven for the poor and have to raise tax burdens—thereby driving away businesses and the more affluent families so important to the tax base.

One way some states will probably use the increased flexibility provided by the PRA is to choose a time limit shorter than five years. This would have dramatic effects on the number of recipients affected, as well as on government outlays (see Figure 4). Other states might choose to continue to provide benefits to unwed minors or to those who have additional children on welfare, using their own funds for this purpose. Most are likely to continue the feverish pace of program experimentation now underway in almost 30 states under federal waivers. But there would be one critical difference: the elimination of the federal requirement that they evaluate and report on the results.

HOW WOULD INDIVIDUALS RESPOND TO THE PRA?
The estimates in the table on page 36 could overstate the long-run effects of the PRA to the extent that it changes childbearing or work patterns so that fewer families require assistance in the future.

Childbearing.

There is little evidence that cash assistance encourages out-of-wedlock childbearing. 9 But total elimination of benefits for unwed teenage mothers has never been tested, and existing research may not be appropriate for assessing this provision. Studies also suggest that benefit increases for children born on welfare (which average $70 a month) have at most a small positive effect on fertility. 10 Very recent, unpublished evidence from New Jersey's welfare reform experiment indicates that the PRA's cap on benefits for additional children may induce a larger response, but it is still too early to assess the reliability of these early estimates.

Work.

Knowing that benefits are time limited is likely to discourage some people from seeking assistance and encourage others to leave the rolls more rapidly. However, there is currently no evidence to predict how large such effects might be.

What about those who reach the time limit and must find other means of support? Those who remain on the rolls for as long as five years are an extremely disadvantaged group. 11 For example, 63 percent of those affected have less than a high school education. Research suggests that most, although not all, of them would try to find jobs—at least part-time jobs. 12 Whether longer-term recipients will be able to obtain and keep jobs, given their lack of education and other personal characteristics, is another question. 13 Under the PRA states could exempt up to 10 percent of their caseload from the limits, acknowledging that some families are not capable of supporting themselves and would face extreme hardship in the absence of cash assistance from the government. But this would not be sufficient to cover all those who are unlikely to become self-supporting or whose presence in the household is essential to the well-being of a child.

CONCLUSION
The PRA would change radically government assist-ance to needy families with children. Virtually all families would be ineligible for benefits after accumulating five years of assistance, and some would no longer receive assistance even in the short run. The PRA would encourage states to adopt still shorter time limits (or other benefit eligibility restrictions). Otherwise, states will need to increase substantially their own spending on welfare over the next five years to meet new federal work requirements and to finance any caseload growth.

Sheila Zedlewski is director of the Income and Benefits Policy Center and Isabel V. Sawhill holds the Arjay Miller Chair in Public Policy at the Urban Institute.

Related Readings:

"Does Welfare Increase Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing?" by Gregory Acs, and "Who Is Affected by Time Limits?" by LaDonna Pavetti, "Welfare Reform Briefs," Numbers 10 and 7, Urban Institute, May 1995.

1. The estimates presented in this issue of Welfare Reform Briefs reflect the contributions of a number of Urban Institute staffers, especially Diane Steffick, Keith Watson, Paul Johnson, Sandra Clark, and Linda Giannarelli.

2. States could exempt up to 10 percent of the caseload from this provision.

3. We use the FY 1993 Quality Control (QC) data describing families receiving benefits under the current program. This file includes 53,000 families representing the average monthly caseload in all 50 states and other U.S. jurisdictions with AFDC programs.

4. To estimate the number of families that would accumulate five years of benefits over a lifetime, we used the following procedure. The QC data provide the length of the current welfare spell and whether or not the family has had a previous spell. We use the 1990-1992 Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) data, showing both current and total spell lengths, for current welfare recipients to impute the length of prior spells for families represented in the QC data. Our estimates indicate that 40 percent of the caseload has accumulated at least five years of benefits and 70 percent has accumulated two or more years of benefits. Pavetti (1994) estimates average total spell lengths of at least five and two years for 48 percent and 70 percent of the caseload, respectively. The relative consistency of the two sets of estimates (using different data and methods) gives us confidence that these estimates are of the right order of magnitude.

5. The food stamp estimates are a simple recalculation of benefits when cash welfare declines. The estimates also incorporate the elimination of food stamp benefits for noncitizens and the reduction in cost-of-living adjustments as provided in the PRA. Food stamp costs will be overstated to the extent that welfare recipients are able to offset the loss in AFDC benefits with earnings. Moreover, it is possible that total growth in the Food Stamp Program will exceed the cap established by the PRA and, therefore, limit the benefit offsets shown. (The cap would be based on the Congressional Budget Office [CBO] projections of food stamp expenditures, taking into account expectations about trends in caseload growth and food stamp benefit reductions included in the PRA.)

6. The average monthly AFDC caseload rose by 33 percent over the five-year period ending in 1993; the growth can be attributed largely to the 1990-1991 recession.

7. There is no new money in the PRA for the expenditures needed to implement the requirement that 27 percent of the caseload be working by the year 2000 and 50 percent by 2003. The CBO estimates that each job slot will cost about $6,000 a year for supervision, child care, monitoring, and case management.

8. This incentive is particularly strong in poorer states with low benefits, where the state match may be as low as 20 percent under current law. As mentioned, the PRA caps food stamp expenditures and potentially may limit these offsets.

9. Gregory Acs, "Do Welfare Benefits Promote Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing?" Welfare Reform Briefs Number 10, Urban Institute, May 1995.

10. Ibid.

11. This is discussed further in "Who Is Affected by Time Limits?" Welfare Reform Briefs Number 7, by LaDonna Pavetti, Urban Institute, May 1995.

12. It turns out that some would be financially better off subsisting on food stamps, Medicaid, and other residual assistance than they would be working, and that many will choose part-time over full-time work because their potential wage rates are low, while child care and other work expenses are high.

13. Welfare Reform Briefs Number 12, by Sandra and Sheldon Danziger addresses this question.

Chapter 9
Will Welfare Recipients Find Work When Welfare Ends?
By Sandra K. Danziger and Sheldon Danziger

Time-limiting welfare is a prominent feature of the current welfare reform debate. The idea first surfaced seven years ago, evolving from a proposal by David Ellwood, currently U.S. Department of Health and Human Services Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. Ellwood proposed that, following a transitional period, a recipient should be expected to earn wages in a regular job or in a work opportunity provided by the government. 1 In the Ellwood scenario, low wages would be supplemented by the earned income tax credit, subsidized child care and medical insurance, and guaranteed child support. Thus, welfare dependency would be reduced by moving nonworking welfare recipients into the labor force and establishing minimum earning levels for them and other working poor families.

The 1995 welfare reform debate, however, has not focused on the labor market in which welfare recipients would be expected to find jobs to support themselves and their families. It would be wise to do so before implementing such a drastic change as time-limiting welfare on a national scale.

The considerable literature on the link between welfare and work is generally in agreement that, over the past two decades, wage rates for those at the bottom of the skill ladder have fallen in real terms, making it more difficult for the unskilled, who make up the bulk of the welfare caseload, to find a job that will support a family. 2 Direct evidence from the experiences of former recipients in Michigan after it terminated its General Assistance (GA) program in 1991 indicates just how inhospitable the low-wage labor market may be for many would-be workers (at least in Michigan), even when they continue to search for work.

THE MICHIGAN GENERAL ASSISTANCE EXPERIENCE
The findings reported are from a stratified random sample of the GA recipient population in Michigan. Their experience over the two years after leaving the welfare program provides insight into what may happen to AFDC recipients whose benefits are similarly terminated, in this case by time limits. 3

Until its October 1991 termination, GA was a state-funded cash program providing $160 per month for nonelderly poor adults without dependent children. In the latter respect the sample differed from the AFDC recipient caseload, but in a way that might make them more rather than less able to find and keep jobs. Most of these GA recipients also received state-provided medical coverage and food stamps, before and after the GA termination.

This was not a population without work experience. Three-quarters of former recipients had labor market experience prior to entering GA. Even with this experience, however, the typical respondent searched for, but did not find, stable employment when the program ended. The respondents were interviewed in 1992, one year after benefits ended, and again in 1993, two years after benefits ended. About 40 percent worked at some point in a regular job, typically as restaurant or janitorial workers, in one or the other of the two post-GA years. 4 In the second post-GA year, a little under a third held a regular job; another half worked at odd jobs or casual labor, such as yard work, babysitting, running errands, etc.

Those who had worked at some point since GA benefits ended but were not working at the second interview were asked why they had left their last job. About half were fired or laid off and another sixth quit for health reasons. The remaining third reported quitting for job-related or personal reasons.

Figure 1 divides the 426 respondents to the second-year post-GA interview into eight mutually exclusive categories representing the principal source of cash support available to them in the month immediately prior to the interview. At that point, only 20 percent of them were employed in formal jobs. On average, they earned $5.50 an hour and worked 34 hours a week in the survey month; more than half of this group reported wanting to work longer hours. One-sixth of the sample had earnings from odd jobs or casual labor.

More than a fourth of respondents relied on disability benefits, and about a tenth relied on AFDC, workers' compensation, unemployment compensation, or pensions. The state of Michigan had expected many recipients to receive financial assistance from family and friends (including private charities). In the year prior to the second post-GA interview, about one-fifth received some cash assistance from friends and about one-third from relatives. The amounts received were quite small because their families and friends also tended to have low incomes. In the month before the second post-GA survey, less than a tenth relied primarily on such help. Another 7 percent relied primarily on a spouse's earnings or benefits. More than one in eight had no cash income from any source listed.

As reflected in their survey responses, the problem was not failure to look for work. Many former recipients reported regular job search efforts and some expressed willingness to work in return for welfare. Many also expressed frustration with their labor market failures. Three examples typify these reactions.

A young man applied in response to a Help Wanted sign at a restaurant. He called back a few days later, but was told that the owner would get back to him. "They never called. So another couple of months later they put another sign up again and I was thinking to myself, if they need that much help, why didn't they hire me, because I qualify for that position?"
Another man entered GA after unemployment compensation ran out following his layoff from an $18-an-hour unionized manufacturing job. During the two post-GA years he found only one part-time janitorial job paying $5.00 an hour. He was laid off from this job after three months and was never called back.
One of the women in the sample completed a commercial business training course "because they guaranteed me a job." She had not found any work in the subsequent two years. She reported that she had sent out 15 to 20 resumes, but had received not a single reply.
Figure 2 presents labor market outcomes for former GA recipients considered most similar to welfare recipients (although GA recipients had no minor children living with them). All male and female respondents (156 from a total sample of 426) who were ages 40 and under in 1991 and who had not qualified for federal or state disability benefits after GA ended were selected. Post-welfare work experience was examined by education level (those who had completed high school or obtained a GED and those who had not).

Two-thirds of this group, regardless of education, held a regular job at some point in the two post-GA years. But the likelihood of regular work depended significantly on education. At the interview two years post-GA, 46 percent of high school graduates were employed, compared with 28 percent of the high school dropouts. The median monthly earnings of the employed were well above the $160 cash general assistance benefit, but still below the poverty line for their family size. Despite the powerful work incentive provided by termination of the program, more than half of the high school graduates remained unemployed.

This is not an encouraging precedent for a time-limited welfare plan that does not provide employment opportunities for welfare mothers unable to find steady work in the regular labor market. These women and their families will no longer be dependent on welfare, but they will be even poorer than they are now.

FINDING WORK IN THE INNER CITY
A recent anthropological study documents the inhospitable nature of the low-wage job market from a different perspective. The study is based on all the job openings filled in 1993 in four fast-food franchises in the Harlem neighborhood of New York. 5 The work histories of the people who got the jobs and the unsuccessful applicants comprised the database. For each job filled, there were 14 job applicants. The job holders were better educated and had better job contacts than the unsuccessful applicants. But the unsuccessful applicants were on average better educated and had more job experience than the typical welfare mother who would face term limits. Of the applicants who were legal immigrants, 40 percent were hired. Of the applicants who were U.S.-born African Americans, only 14 percent were hired. Three-quarters of the rejected applicants continued to search for work but were unemployed when interviewed a year later.

CONCLUSION
The Michigan experience after the termination of its GA program suggests that many current welfare recipients may not find steady employment, even at low wages, if time limits were implemented. One reason is the considerable evidence that employers prefer to hire those with more labor-market skills and experience rather than less. It is the latter group, by and large, that will come up against time limits, if the Personal Responsibility Act or something like it becomes law.

If government enacts time limits without providing some way for former recipients to "work for welfare" or take minimum-wage public-service jobs of last resort, considerably more hardship may result than what the terms of the current debate suggest.

Related Readings:

America Unequal, by Sheldon Danziger and Peter Gottschalk, Harvard University Press, forthcoming.

Finding Work in the Inner City, by Katherine Newman, Columbia University Department of Anthropology, February 1995.

Poor Support: Poverty and the American Family, by David Ellwood, Basic Books, 1988.

"Welfare Realities: From Rhetoric to Reform," by Mary Jo Bane and David Ellwood, Harvard University Press, 1994.

"When Welfare Ends: Subsistence Strategies of Former GA Recipients," by Sandra K. Danziger and Sherrie A. Kossoudji, University of Michigan School of Social Work, February 1995.

Sandra K. Danziger is an associate professor of social work at the University of Michigan. Sheldon Danziger is a professor of social work and public policy at the University of Michigan.

1. David Ellwood, Poor Support: Poverty and the American Family, Basic Books, 1988.

2. See, for example, Mary Jo Bane and David Ellwood, Welfare Realities: From Rhetoric to Reform, Harvard University Press, 1994; and Sheldon Danziger and Peter Gottschalk, America Unequal, Harvard University Press, forthcoming.

3. Sandra K. Danziger and Sherrie A. Kossoudji, When Welfare Ends: Subsistence Strategies of Former GA Recipients, University of Michigan School of Social Work, 1995. A stratified random sample was drawn from administrative data on the March 1991 recipient population from five counties, selected to represent urban and rural areas. Location rates varied considerably by county. The most difficult part of the survey design was contacting former recipients for the initial 1992 interview. Only about one-third of the Wayne County (Detroit) sample and about half of the sample in each of the other four counties could be located. Once located, however, refusal rates were less than 10 percent. In 1992, about one year after GA ended, 530 former recipients were interviewed. In 1993, 426 of the original respondents completed the second survey. For both surveys, structured, in-person interviews took place at the respondents' residences and lasted about an hour each.

4. The 426 respondents interviewed in 1993 can be categorized into four groups based on work experience prior to entering GA and work in the two years following termination_51.5 percent worked before, but not after; 25.7 percent worked before and after; 12.3 percent had no prior work experience, but worked after; and 10.5 percent never worked.

5. Katherine Newman, Finding Work in the Inner City, Columbia University Department of Anthropology, February 1995.

Chapter 10
Teenage Childbearing: The Trends and Their Implications
By Freya L. Sonestein and Gregory Acs

Recent welfare proposals from both sides of the aisle in Congress have focused in an unprecedented way on teenage parents and their children. While earlier reforms like the Family Support Act of 1988 concentrated on job training, supportive services, and child support enforcement, the new reforms acknowledge the need to reduce teenage childbearing. But this consensus on the goal is not matched by agreement on how to achieve it.

The welfare legislation recently passed by the House proposes to replace Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) and related programs with a block grant to states, which ends universal eligibility for cash assistance among those meeting federal program criteria. Key features of this legislation include its "affirmation of the value of marriage" and its intent to "diminish the number of teenage pregnancies and illegitimate births." It proposes to achieve these goals, respectively, by denying benefits to children born to mothers already on welfare and denying benefits to children born to unmarried minor mothers.

The Clinton Administration has embraced the concept of "promoting parental responsibility and preventing teen pregnancy." To achieve this, the administration's 1994 proposal concentrated services on young parents applying for welfare - those born after 1971. Minors would receive special case management services, and would be required to live at home with their parents (with exceptions for just cause) and to stay in school. The proposal also included a national campaign against teen pregnancy with increased funding for Title X family planning programs; grants to about 1000 schools and community organizations to implement "teen pregnancy prevention" efforts; demonstration grants to as many as seven high-risk, low-income neighborhoods to implement comprehensive social and health services with an emphasis on pregnancy prevention; and a national clearinghouse to evaluate and disseminate information on effective programs.

TRENDS IN CHILDBEARING AMONG TEENAGERS
In light of the current widespread recognition among legislators and the general public that teenage childbearing is a serious social problem, it may come as a surprise that actual birth rates among teenagers are substantially lower today than they were in 1960. In 1960, 89 out of 1000 females ages 15-19 bore a child. By 1980, that birth rate had declined to 53 per 1000 females. It then remained relatively stable for several years, reaching its lowest point in 1986 at 50 per 1000. Since 1986 it has been rising, increasing to 61 per 1000 in 1992 (see chart, Figure 1). The 1992 statistics show some leveling off, but it is not yet clear if this is a trend.

Birth rates to teenagers outside marriage have been increasing, however - a trend that is true also for older women. Since 1960 the birth rate for unwed teenagers has tripled, from 15 to 45 births per 1000 unmarried females ages 15-19. The nonmarital birthrate for teenagers, however, consistently lags behind the nonmarital birth rate for women in their 20s (see chart, Figure 2).

Underlying these trends in teenage fertility are the following changes in marriage patterns, sexual behavior, contraceptive practices, abortion, and the ethnic composition of the teenage population:

Young men and women are increasingly delaying marriage. In 1960, 14 percent of young women ages 15-19 were married. By 1992, the proportion was less than 5 percent.
Teenagers are becoming sexually experienced at younger ages. In 1970, 29 percent of 15- to 19-year-old females were sexually experienced, increasing to 52 percent in 1988. Thus, proportionately more teenagers are exposed to the risk of pregnancy and to the risk of nonmarital pregnancy.
Contraception among sexually active teenagers has increased. This is primarily the result of increased condom use. Higher contraceptive use has partially offset the potential increase in pregnancy from increased sexual activity.
Declining abortion rates have increased the number of births resulting from pregnancies. In 1972, just prior to Roe v. Wade, one-quarter of all pregnant teenagers terminated their pregnancies. This proportion grew to 46 percent in 1984 and remained steady for several years. But by 1990 the abortion rate for pregnant teenagers had fallen to 40 percent. The rise in birth rates among teenagers since 1986 can be partly explained by the declining abortion rates.
Birth rates are higher among black and Hispanic teenagers than among white teenagers. The teenage birth rate for Hispanic females was 112 per 1000 in 1992. For blacks it was slightly higher at 116. For white females, 42 out of 1000 teenagers bore a child. Recent increases in birth rates among teenagers may be partly attributable to increases in the numbers of Hispanic teens, who have high fertility rates. Between 1986 and 1991 the number of Hispanic teens increased 12 percent, while the number of non-Hispanic white teens decreased 14 percent. 1
Summary of Trends: The teen birth rate today is considerably lower than it was 35 years ago, although somewhat higher than a decade ago. More births occur outside marriage among teens as well as among older women. Increases in sexual experience among teenagers over this period have not resulted in higher birth rates because of increased reliance on contraception and abortion. The recent upturn in teen birth rates is linked to decreases in abortion and to shifts in the composition of the teenage population as the number of Hispanic teens increases. There is no evidence that birth rates among teenagers are rising because more teenagers desire to be parents. Only one-quarter of births to teenagers in 1987 were reported to be intended births.
THE LINK BETWEEN AFDC AND TEEN CHILDBEARING
Although a very small proportion of the current AFDC caseload is composed of families or subfamilies headed by teenage mothers, many older women on AFDC had their first child when they were teenagers. In 1992, mothers under age 20 made up 8 percent of AFDC cases, but 52 percent of the mothers on AFDC had their first children as teenagers. In 1992, total AFDC expenditures for these mothers and their families were estimated at $12.8 billion. 2

Since 1975, the proportion of AFDC mothers who had their first birth as a teenager has been virtually stable, despite the sharp increase in births among unmarried teens. Thus, rising proportions of nonmarital births among older women may have balanced out any growth in the AFDC caseload that is the result of teenage nonmarital childbearing.

Women who have children as teenagers are more likely to be poor than women who defer childbearing. Analysts are still trying to sort out, however, to what extent the unfavorable economic outcomes are the result of the birth itself rather than preexisting circumstances - like growing up in poverty and having limited educational opportunities.

THE LINK BETWEEN POVERTY AND TEEN CHILDBEARING
Considerable evidence indicates that adolescents from poor families or those with educational deficiencies are more likely than other demographic groups to initiate sexual activity at earlier ages. Although their use of contraception does not appear different from like-aged youth from more advantaged families, contraceptive failure rates are higher and the proportion of unplanned pregnancies ending in abortion is lower. As a result, adolescents in poverty or with educational deficits (which are overlapping populations) are more likely to bear a child. An unplanned birth to a teenager who already faces a bleak economic future is likely to compound the difficulties she faces as she strives to be self-sufficient. However, some women who become mothers as teenagers avoid poverty in their twenties if they complete school and eventually marry.

THE LIVING ARRANGEMENTS OF TEENAGE PARENTS ON WELFARE
Very few mothers under age 18 and on welfare set up separate households. According to the 1990 census, more than half of these mothers (58 percent) live with their parents. Eighteen percent live alone with their children. Twelve percent live with a spouse, and 12 percent live with other adults, which can include cohabiting partners. Thus, in the majority of cases, availability of welfare does not appear to induce poor teens to have children so that they can leave the parental home. Mothers who are older teens (18 and 19) are much more likely to live alone with their children (46 percent) and less likely to live with a parent (33 percent). Given the small number of unmarried teens under the age of 18 who live alone, denying cash benefits to teens may have little effect on the living arrangements of these mothers, but the incomes of the families caring for them will be reduced significantly.

WHAT ABOUT THE FATHERS?
The limited data available on the fathers of the children born to teens under age 18 on AFDC indicate that less than one quarter of these fathers are themselves under the age of 18. On average these fathers are 3.5 years older than the mothers. But a small group of fathers are significantly older. Twenty-one percent of young welfare mothers (under age 18) had partners who were at least five years older. These data suggest that increased paternity establishment and child support enforcement might net more resources for the family than is commonly believed, although an estimated 29 percent of fathers are dropouts or are at least two years behind in school.

While the Personal Responsibility Act (H.R.4) may result in more marriages, paternity establishment, and child support enforcement, the effects of these changes on the well-being of very young mothers and their children are unclear. Some babies born to very young mothers are the result of involuntary sexual encounters. In one survey, three-quarters of females who had sexual intercourse before age 14 reported having had sex involuntarily. Policies that encourage more interaction between fathers and young mothers need mechanisms to exempt young mothers from required contact when abuse is involved.

By denying benefits to those under age 18, the pending legislation may encourage more marriages among the very young. But those marriages are not very durable. Also, young mothers who marry tend to experience reduced educational attainment which interferes with their and their families' ability to achieve self-sufficiency.

CONCLUSION
One objective of welfare reform - shared by both political parties_is to reduce teenage childbearing. However, reducing teenage childbearing is likely to require more than manipulating welfare program participation rules. The key behaviors underlying current trends in teenage childbearing are sexual activity, contraceptive use, and pregnancy resolution (marriage, adoption, abortion, or out-of-wedlock birth). As detailed in an earlier brief, there is little evidence that welfare benefits affect out-of-wedlock childbearing. 3 However, to the extent that they do, it is more likely that they affect pregnancy resolution than sexual activity or the use of contraception. Thus, denial of benefits may have the perverse consequence of increasing abortions and unintended marriages.

If legislators want to reduce teenage childbearing, they are likely to be most successful with policies and programs that are targeted directly to the behaviors that lead to teenage pregnancies—sexual activity and contraceptive use.

Freya L. Sonenstein is director of the Population Studies Center and Gregory Acs is a senior research associate at the Urban Institute.

Related Readings

"Sex and America's Teenagers," The Alan Guttmacher Institute, 1994.

"What Is Happening to Out-of-Wedlock Teenage Child-bearing?" by Christine Bachrach et al., Sexuality and American Policy Series, American Enterprise Institute, 1995.

"Trends in Pregnancy and Pregnancy Rates: Estimates for the United States, 1980-92," Stephanie Ventura et al., Monthly Vital Statistics Report, National Center for Health Statistics, forthcoming.

"The Effects of the Sequencing of Marriage and First Birth during Adolescence," Steven D. McLaughlin et al., Family Planning Perspectives, vol. 18, no. 1, January/February 1986, pp. 12-18.

1. Stephanie Ventura et al., Trends in Pregnancy and Pregnancy Rates: Estimates for the Unites States, 1980-92, National Center for Health Statistics, forthcoming.

2. Kristin A. Moore, Background Data on Teenage Fertility, Child Trends, Inc., February 1995, special tabulations.

3. Gregory Acs, "Does Welfare Increase Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing?" Welfare Reform Brief Number 10, Urban Institute, May 1995.

Chapter 11
Do Welfare Benefits Promote Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing?
By Gregory Acs

Under the current U.S. welfare system, an unmarried woman with no income can have a child and receive an average of more than $3,500 a year in cash assistance from the Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) program. 1 This cash provides an unambiguous financial incentive for poor women to have children outside of marriage. Such a perverse incentive, combined with rising out-of-wedlock birth rates, has prompted leading policy analysts and legislators to recommend eliminating welfare assistance to teens completely. The 104th House of Representatives, for instance, has passed legislation abolishing AFDC and replacing it with a block grant that prohibits states from using federal funds to provide cash assistance to teenage single mothers. Such reforms are intended to reduce dramatically the number of children born out of wedlock to mothers who need public assistance. Will the reforms accomplish their objective?

Essentially, this is a question of why women have children out of wedlock and why nonmarital births have been on the rise. Presumably, single women have children for many of the same reasons that married women do. For young women with low socioeconomic status, however, the love provided by a child and the attention and respect accorded to motherhood in the community may be especially important. 2 The rewards of child rearing may appear especially high compared to their other life options. And the cash and other public assistance available to single mothers with children could influence the decision to have a child out of wedlock. But how important is the lure of such welfare assistance relative to other factors?

Some argue that welfare is a critical, enabling factor and that reducing or eliminating benefits would reduce the number of nonmarital births substantially. Others argue that young women are not "future oriented" and do not consider the financial implications of their childbearing decisions. Ultimately, the impact of welfare on women's childbearing decisions is an empirical question. What is the evidence?

NONMARITAL BIRTHRATE TRENDS
Whether one considers the nonmarital birth ratio (the share of nonmarital to all births) or the non- marital birth rate (the number of births per 1,000 unmarried women of childbearing age), out-of-wedlock childbearing has been on the rise (see Figure 1). Between 1960 and 1990, the nonmarital birth ratio increased fivefold, from 5.3 to 28.0 percent of all births. But it is important to remember that the nonmarital birth ratio can increase if the behavior of single women remains unchanged but fewer married women have children. Thus, it is important to look at the nonmarital birth rate to see whether single women are having more children.

While overall birth rates have dropped from about 88 per 1,000 women of childbearing age in 1970 to 69 births per 1,000 in 1992, the nonmarital birth rate has increased from about 26 to 45. Can welfare be held responsible for this rise?

Some argue that it has played such a role, but this is a difficult case to make. In nominal terms, welfare pays more now, but inflation has eroded most of its value. Since 1970, the real value of AFDC plus food stamps has decreased by more than 25 percent (see Figure 2). The main reason government expenditures on the poor have risen is the skyrocketing cost of Medicaid. But from the point of view of the welfare recipient, Medicaid buys about the same coverage today as in the past: in 1970, the recipient could see a doctor if she or her child got sick; the same is true in 1995. Thus, on balance, a woman on welfare is worse off in 1995 than she was in 1970. Consequently, it is difficult to attribute the rising out-of-wedlock birth rates to rising welfare benefits because, from the point of view of the recipients, benefits have decreased.

THE ATTRACTIVENESS OF ALTERNATIVES TO WELFARE
While a woman on welfare is financially worse off today then a woman on welfare 25 years ago, the alternatives to welfare - work and marriage - also may have grown less attractive. Indeed, given the profound changes in the economy over the past 25 years, perhaps welfare has become a relatively more attractive source of financial support than the alternatives. The financial returns associated with working over the past 25 years have remained about the same for less-skilled women. Their wages did not worsen appreciably, and their employers still rarely provide much in the way of health and other benefits. But the job market for less-skilled and even medium-skilled men has declined precipitously. For example, the real hourly wages of men with only a high school diploma fell by 20 percent between 1973 and 1993. 3 Thus, while welfare has become less attractive over time, the attractiveness of marriage, from a purely economic perspective, also has declined.

STATE WELFARE BENEFITS AND OUT-OF-WEDLOCK CHILDBEARING
Even if there is not a direct correlation between the rise in out-of-wedlock births and trends in benefit generosity, welfare benefits may still influence childbearing decisions. The cornerstone of cash assistance to poor single mothers is AFDC, and AFDC benefits vary from state to state. Thus, if women respond to the monetary incentive to have children, we would expect to see women in higher-benefit states having more children out of wedlock; but this is not the case. Simple comparisons show, in contrast, that nonmarital births are more common in states with lower benefit levels.

These comparisons, however, while straightforward, also can be quite misleading. Low-benefit states may have lower costs of living and/or have a disproportionate number of women at high risk for nonmarital childbearing. Ideally, a thorough analysis would control for differences in young women's own characteristics as well as differences in the states where they live when trying to isolate the impact of welfare on their decisions to have children out of wedlock. Further, it would be important also to control for the benefit levels and economic circumstan-ces at the time the childbearing decisions were being made.

Unfortunately, no study with these and other necessary controls exists. But many studies using different data sets and slightly different methodologies come up with a relatively consistent finding: white women living in states with higher welfare benefits are a little more likely to have children out of wedlock than white women living in lower-benefit states. But nonmarital births among black and Hispanic women are not significantly correlated with the generosity of welfare (see summary of studies, Figure 3).

The decisions of young mothers on welfare to have additional children also have garnered considerable attention at both federal and state levels. While only a few studies explore the impact of welfare on subsequent births, none finds a direct impact of welfare on continued childbearing. In 1992, New Jersey began denying benefit increases to welfare mothers when they have additional children. Evaluating the impact of this major policy change will greatly enhance our knowledge in this area. However, only preliminary data exist at this time.

Finally, is there any evidence that welfare deters marriage? Yes, there is. Young mothers and pregnant women are slightly less likely to marry in states with higher benefits. In fact, one study finds that virtually the entire impact of welfare on nonmarital births among white teenagers is not through increased pregnancy but through reduced "legitimation." 4

All this research employs techniques designed to examine the impact of relatively small changes in benefit levels on birth outcomes. It is indefensible to extrapolate from these results to recommendations for major changes in the nation's welfare system. Claims that eliminating welfare will virtually eliminate "illegitimacy" are simultaneously unsupportable and irrefutable by conventional social science. Moreover, even if it were the case that by eliminating welfare the nonmarital birth rate would be cut in half, other potential outcomes need to be considered, such as the impact of a policy of this kind on the half-million children who still would be born out of wedlock every year. For most of these children, eliminating welfare would mean subjecting them to lives of intensified poverty, with the serious and long-term negative consequences known to be associated with this condition.

CONCLUSION
In sum, the problem of increasing out-of-wedlock childbirth will likely persist even if welfare is eliminated. Reducing nonmarital childbearing remains an important goal for social policy, but other factors that contribute to out-of-wedlock births should be considered. To the extent that nonmarital birth rates are higher today than three decades ago - not because more women are having children, but because fewer women are marrying - policies aimed at increasing the attractiveness of marriage and the value of work make sense. Such policies could include reducing or eliminating marriage penalties in the tax code and providing education, training, and jobs to young men as well as to young women. Such reforms could raise the monetary value of work and marriage and reduce the attractiveness of welfare dependency. At the same time, it must be recognized that there are larger cultural trends at work here that government may be powerless to reverse.

Gregory Acs is a senior research associate at the Urban Institute.

Related Readings:

"Effects of State Welfare, Abortion, and Family Planning Policies on Premarital Childbearing Among White Adolescents," by Shelly Lundberg and Robert Plotnick, "FamilyPlanning Perspectives," vol. 22, no. 6, 1990, pp. 246-251.

"Fertility Among Women on Welfare: Incidence and Determinants," by Mark Rank, "American Sociological Review," vol. 54, April 1989, pp. 296-304.

"The Impact of Welfare on Young Women's Childbearing Decisions," by Gregory Acs, Urban Institute, 1995.

"Teen Out-of-Wedlock Births and Welfare Receipt: The Role of Childhood Events and Economic Circumstances," by Chong-Bum An, Robert Haveman, and Barbara Wolfe, "The Review of Economics and Statistics," vol. 75, no. 2, 1993, pp. 195-208.

"Underclass Behavior in the United States: Measurement and Analysis of Determinants," by Anne M. Hill and June O'Neill, Report to the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Washington, D.C., 1993.

"Welfare Benefits, Economic Opportunities, and Out-of-Wedlock Births Among Black Teenage Girls," by Greg Duncan and Saul Hoffman, "Demography," vol. 27, no. 4, November1990, pp. 519-535.

"Welfare Benefits and Family-Size Decisions of Never-Married Women," by Philip Robins and Paul Fronstin, Discussion Paper 1022-93, Institute for Research on Poverty, University of Wisconsin, 1993.

"Welfare and the Family: The U.S. Experience," by Charles Murray, "Journal of Labor Economics," vol. 11, no. 1, pt. 2, 1993, pp. S224-S262.

"Welfare and Out-of-Wedlock Childbearing: Evidence from the 1980s," by Robert Plotnick, "Journal of Marriage and the Family," vol. 52, no. 3, August 1990, pp. 735-746.

"The Impact of the AFDC Benefit Schedule on Birth Decisions and Program Participation," by Elizabeth Powers, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 1994.

1. Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, Overview of Entitlement Programs: 1993 Green Book (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1993-1994).

2. See Elijah Anderson, "Sex Codes and Family Life Among Poor Inner-City Youths," in Young Unwed Fathers: Changing Roles and Emerging Policies, edited by Robert I. Lerman and Theodora J. Ooms (Temple University Press, 1993).

3. Economic Report of the President, February 1995, p. 175.

4. Shelly Lundberg and Robert Plotnick, "Effects of State Welfare, Abortion, and Family Planning Policies on Premarital Childbearing Among White Adolescents," Family Planning Perspectives, vol. 22, no. 6, 1990, pp. 246-251.

Chapter 12
The Benefits on Increased Child Support Enforcement
By Elaine Sorensen

Child support reform is a critical component of the current welfare debate. The nearly universal support for it among federal legislators stems, in part, from the expectation that increased child support payments can reduce poverty, welfare dependency, and welfare costs. This note reviews the evidence on this issue and concludes that:

Noncustodial fathers could pay as much as $34 billion more in child support under an ideal child support system—that is, one in which all noncustodial fathers have a legal obligation set according to the Wisconsin child support guidelines and those obligations are fully paid.
Under an ideal child support system, poverty and welfare costs among custodial families would decline modestly, with an additional $7 billion of child support going to poor mothers and their children. Although $7 billion is modest relative to the total amount of child support collected, it is quite sizable relative to the likely impact of other policy efforts to improve the economic situation of poor mothers and their children.
The reason for the modest effects on poverty and welfare costs is that 13 to 26 percent of the noncustodial fathers are poor or have extremely low incomes, limiting their ability to pay child support.
While an ideal child support system may be a worthy policy goal, it is currently out of reach, because the largest part of the problem is that child support is not always awarded, and establishing those awards is a major undertaking.
WHAT IS THE BASIS FOR THE ESTIMATE OF $34 BILLION?
According to Census data from the 1990 Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP), noncustodial fathers paid, on average, only 7 percent of their income in child support. This figure is low primarily because over half of the noncustodial fathers paid no child support. Even among those fathers who paid, more than half spent less than 15 percent of their income on child support.

How much more noncustodial fathers could pay can be estimated by comparing actual child support payments with the child support guidelines Wisconsin uses to determine child support awards. The Wisconsin guidelines are selected because they are easy to understand and they are widely known. In addition, they are not radically different from other states' guidelines, all of which are based indirectly on studies of the cost of raising children.

The state of Wisconsin applies the following percentages to the noncustodial parent's income to determine a child support award: 17 percent for one child, 25 percent for two children, 29 percent for three children, 31 percent for four, and 34 percent for five or more.

Using the Wisconsin guidelines, Urban Institute research shows that noncustodial fathers could pay as much as $34 billion more in child support. This represents a three-fold increase in child support payments.

Three factors contribute to the gap between potential and actual child support payments (see Figure 1).

First, not all existing child support awards are paid. One-third of ordered support went uncollected in 1990, representing $7 billion that year. Second, most awards do not reflect parents' current ability to pay child support. Awards are typically set in fixed dollar amounts that are not updated to reflect changes in the income of either parent or the cost of raising children. If child support awards were adjusted to reflect the current income of noncustodial fathers using the Wisconsin guidelines, another $7 billion of child support would have been awarded in 1990. Third, in many cases there is no child support order. An additional $20 billion could be collected if child support orders were required of every noncustodial father.

CAN ALL NONCUSTODIAL FATHERS AFFORD CHILD SUPPORT?
Although noncustodial fathers as a whole could pay more child support, some could not. In 1990, 13 to 26 percent of noncustodial fathers either lived in a poor family or had personal incomes below $6,800, which was the poverty threshold for an individual that year (see Figure 2). These poverty statistics are even more stark for black noncustodial fathers: 23 to 56 percent of these fathers were poor or had poverty-level incomes in 1990. Almost 90 percent of noncustodial fathers who were poor or had poverty-level incomes in 1990 did not work or worked intermittently that year; nearly half of them had not completed high school.

Under the Wisconsin guidelines, these fathers are not expected to pay much, if any, child support because their incomes are too low, and asking them to contribute would simply shift poverty from one group to another. An important point to keep in mind, however, is that many of these men who cannot afford to pay support are the fathers of the children on Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC).

WHAT CAN INCREASED CHILD SUPPORT PAYMENTS ACHIEVE?
The current child support enforcement system has a modest effect on reducing poverty, welfare dependency, and welfare costs. For example, 800,000 individuals escaped poverty in 1989 because they received child support. But 11.9 million individuals in custodial families remained poor that year.

Under current law, custodial families must assign their rights to collect child support to the state in order to receive benefits from AFDC. Child support collected on behalf of custodial families is distributed partly to the government and partly to the family. AFDC families receive the first $50 of child support collected on their behalf each month. The government retains funds above that to reimburse it for AFDC payments made to the family. In 1989, noncustodial fathers of AFDC children paid $1.5 billion in child support, most of which was retained by the government to help cover the $12 billion in AFDC benefits received by custodial families that year.

What would have happened under an ideal child support system—that is, one in which every noncustodial father had a child support obligation set according to the Wisconsin guidelines, and all orders were fully collected?

Total welfare costs (i.e., AFDC, Food Stamps, and Medicaid) would have fallen by 9 percent, or $5 billion.
AFDC participation would have dropped by 9 percent, resulting in 400,000 families leaving AFDC.
The poverty rate would have declined by 5 percent, lifting 1.4 million individuals out of poverty (see Figure 3). 1
Thus, an ideal child support system would have modest impacts on welfare costs and poverty because only $7 billion, about 20 percent of the additional child support collected, would go to poor mothers and their children.

While $5 billion of welfare savings is small relative to the total amount of child support that could be collected under an ideal child support system, this number should be placed in a larger policy context. For example, one of the cost-saving measures included in this year's welfare reform legislation is to convert AFDC into block grants to the states. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that the gross savings from this proposal would be $8 billion over five years, with less than $1 billion of savings in the first year and $2.6 billion in the fifth year. This level of savings could probably be achieved through increased child support enforcement.

WILL ANOTHER $34 BILLION OF CHILD SUPPORT BE COLLECTED?
The $34 billion estimate assumes that three conditions are met: (1) every noncustodial father has been assigned a child support obligation; (2) those awards are set according to the Wisconsin guidelines; and (3) those awards are paid in full. Although assigning every noncustodial father a child support obligation and getting them paid in full may be worthy goals, it is unrealistic to expect to achieve them fully in the near future. In 1990, nearly one-quarter of custodial families without awards said they did not want them. Another 15 percent said that the father could not be located. These figures may change as it becomes easier to obtain awards and locate fathers. But even under the best of circumstances, some families will not pursue a child support award and some fathers will not be located. Furthermore, in 1990 only two-thirds of ordered child support was collected. The collections rate may improve under the proposed reforms, but it is unlikely to reach 100 percent.

Even if these two goals are met, there is no guarantee that awards will be set at the level implied by the Wisconsin guidelines. Each state has enacted its own guidelines for determining child support awards. And many are less generous than those used in Wisconsin. Furthermore, judicial discretion is permitted when setting child support awards. Even in Wisconsin, awards are established according to the Wisconsin guidelines only about half the time.

Although an ideal child support system may be out of reach, it is instructive to understand the potential effects of such a system on poverty and welfare costs. Incremental changes—establishing more awards, increasing award levels, and collecting more of the award amount—can be achieved in the current political climate. And even without reaching the full potential of an ideal child support system, these actions can still improve individual poor families' ability to raise themselves out of poverty and reduce their dependence on the federal welfare system.

Elaine Sorensen is a senior research assoscate at the Urban Instititute.

Related Readings:

"Child Support and Child Well-Being." Edited by Irwin Garfinkel, Sara S. McLanahan, and Philip K. Robins, Urban Institute Press, 1994.

"Noncustodial Fathers: Can They Afford to Pay More Child Support?" Elaine Sorensen, Urban Institute, February 1995.

"Potential Effects of Increased Child Support Enforcement on Poverty, Welfare Costs, and Welfare Dependency." Elaine Sorensen and Laura Wheaton, Urban Institute, forthcoming 1995.

1. These estimates are based on the Urban Institute's microsimulation model (TRIM2), using Census data from the Current Population Survey on custodial mothers. Information about noncustodial fathers' income is not directly available but is added to the file using information about the characteristics of the mothers. Although the effects of an ideal child support system are estimated using imputed income for noncustodial fathers, the imputed income is very similar to the actual income of noncustodial fathers observed in the 1990 SIPP. For example, both sets of data find that noncustodial fathers could have paid $48 billion in child support under an ideal child support system in 1989.

Chapter 13
The Food Stamp Program and the Safety Net
By James C. Ohls

The Food Stamp Program is the only major public benefit program for which eligibility is based solely on need, irrespective of residence or type of family. As such, it is the cornerstone of America's "safety net" for assisting low-income Americans. With current annual expenditures of $27 billion, the Food Stamp Program serves one in 11 Americans in an average month. This wide reach underlines the importance of considering the role of food stamps in the overall system of income support, and how that role may change if the proposals contemplated in the House-passed Personal Responsibility Act (H.R.4), or something similar to them, become law.

FOOD STAMPS: A PROGRAM OVERVIEW
The Food Stamp Program is an uncapped entitlement with need-based national eligibility and benefit provisions. Benefits are financed entirely by the federal government, although states have to contribute 50 percent of the program's administrative costs. Begun as a pilot program at local discretion in 1961, food stamps became a national program when federal eligibility criteria and benefit levels were established in 1970. To be eligible for food stamps, a household's gross income must be less than 130 percent of the poverty level for that family size, and its net income (after allowable shelter and work-related deductions) no higher than the poverty line. Total assets (excluding a family's home) must be less than $2,000. 1

Benefit levels, based on the cost of a low-budget, nutritious diet, depend on family size and are adjusted annually to keep pace with inflation. The food stamp benefit formula interacts with state-set AFDC benefit levels. The lower the AFDC benefit, the higher the food stamp benefit in that state.

Since 1985, there has been a job-search and training requirement for adult food stamp recipients who are not elderly, disabled, or already subject to work requirements by their receipt of AFDC.

THE ROLE OF THE PROGRAM
Because it is noncategorical, is adjusted for inflation, and interacts with AFDC benefit levels, the Food Stamp Program plays a major integrating and stabilizing role in the nation's public assistance system. The program:

Provides a universal safety net.
The importance of food stamps as the only part of the safety net available to all who may fall on hard times is highlighted by the diversity of the caseload (see Figure 1). Somewhat more than 60 percent of food stamp households include children, although only 40 percent of recipient households are also on AFDC. More than 25 percent contain a family member who is elderly or disabled. The remaining caseload reflects diverse overlapping groups, including the working poor, the homeless, and individuals on state or local general assistance.

In addition to providing universal eligibility based on need, the Food Stamp Program sets a nationally uniform minimum benefit level. A major factor in the decision to impose federal standards was a strong political consensus that eliminating hunger and malnutrition is a national objective in the face of evidence of substantial state disparities in meeting this objective.

Provides broader income support as well as food.
It has been argued that restricting the benefit to food reduces its effectiveness as an income support system. The other side of this argument is that the benefit form was designed precisely to ensure that beneficiaries spent enough on food.

Evidence indicates that both the food consumption and income-support functions are being met. For the typical family, an additional dollar of coupon benefits increases food expenditures by between 20 and 40 cents. 2 The remaining 60 to 80 cents of the food stamp benefit dollar are freed up to meet other needs. Food often represents the largest item in many low-income family budgets, and the food stamp benefit - particularly in states with low AFDC benefits—represents the single largest source of household purchasing power.

Reduces interstate benefit disparities
AFDC benefit levels vary widely by state. The food stamp benefit formula reduces this variation by increasing the food stamp benefit by 30 cents for each dollar reduction in the AFDC benefit. In 1991, the combined AFDC and food stamp maximum benefit in Mississippi was $5,900, compared with $11,900 in California. This disparity is still far greater than what is justified by regional cost-of-living differences, but it is 50 percent less than it would be without the interactive food stamp benefit formula. 3

Softens the Impact of Economic Fluctuations.
Inflation erodes the value of a fixed benefit and rising unemployment increases the number of families needing assistance.

AFDC has no automatic adjustment for benefit erosion caused by inflation. The Food Stamp Program's automatic cost-of-living adjustment, in contrast, preserves the real value of a recipient household's food purchasing power.

Under current law, AFDC caseloads can expand as unemployment increases the number of families in need. But the nature of the AFDC caseload renders its countercyclical impact quite modest. During the 1989-1992 recession, AFDC participation increased by only about 11 percent. 4

The Food Stamp Program has a larger countercyclical impact, given the greater proportion of working poor in its caseload. Food Stamp Program participation was stable (in the 18 to 20 million range) between 1980 and 1988. During the 1989-1992 recession, participation rose from 18.8 million to 25 million persons, almost a 25 percent increase. 5

CHANGES PROPOSED IN H.R.4
H.R.4 includes six major provisions that would affect the Food Stamp Program. The act:

limits cost-of-living adjustments to 2 percent a year, less than the current inflation rate for food;
imposes a work requirement that ends food stamp eligibility after three months for able-bodied food stamp recipients ages 18 to 50 without dependents;
freezes the ceiling on the deduction from gross income for very high shelter costs, which is included in determinations of eligibility and calculations of benefits;
permits any state that implements electronic benefit transfer (EBT) to opt for a flat-funded block grant;
allows states additional flexibility in setting food stamp eligibility and benefit rules for their AFDC populations; and
makes most legal immigrants ineligible for food stamps.
IMPACTS ON THE PROGRAM'S ROLE
These changes would greatly reduce the integrating and stabilizing role the Food Stamp Program now plays in the U.S. income support system. 6 (Outright block granting of food stamps would almost certainly eliminate that part of its role entirely.)

First, universal noncategorical eligibility would be lost. Able-bodied adults ages 18 to 50 without dependents would no longer be guaranteed assistance. Benefits for welfare recipients could be reduced or cashed out. In addition, any state opting for the EBT block grant option would be free to make all program choices.

Second, the antipoverty effect of food stamps would be weakened, as the 2 percent cap on the cost-of-living adjustment and the absolute cap on the shelter deduction ceiling progressively reduce the real value of the benefit.

Finally, the proposed benefit cuts and increased state discretion would weaken the power of the Food Stamp Program to reduce interstate disparities in AFDC benefit levels_disparities that are likely to increase with the block granting of AFDC.

FOOD STAMP OBJECTIVES OF H.R.4
The proposed changes are designed to meet the following set of specific objectives:

Cut costs.

H.R.4 food stamp provisions would produce savings estimated by the Congressional Budget Office at $23 billion over the first five years. The benefit reductions (compared to what would have been provided under current law) would be relatively small at first but would increase over time. The 1996 cut would be 7 percent. By the year 2000 the cut would be 21 percent. By 2005 it would reach 30 percent. 7

Reduce fraud and abuse.

The U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) estimates that about 8 percent of the food stamp benefit expenditures are overpayments or payments to ineligible households. In addition, there is undoubtedly some trafficking (clients exchanging stamps at a discount for cash), although there are no reliable estimates of its extent. H.R.4's emphasis on state administration and EBT is designed to reduce both types of fraud. A recent USDA investigation shows that the EBT system is not completely invulnerable to fraud. But there is general consensus that it discourages fraud and leaves better audit trails when fraud does occur.

Increase work effort.

The withdrawal of benefits from able-bodied prime-age adults without dependents is designed to provide a powerful incentive to work. The current food stamp employment and training program is widely agreed to be ineffective in increasing employment. One problem is that those subject to the requirement are typically very poorly educated and hard to help. In addition, program funding (at $75 million) is grossly inadequate to provide the education, training, and job search assistance needed to make a real difference in the employability of these recipients. H.R.4 includes funding only at the same level.

Increase state control for better administration.
The argument for more state control is that increased flexibility allows states to be more responsive to local program needs and to save the costs otherwise incurred by having to meet federal standards. With respect to food stamps, the states already have direct responsibility for and considerable leeway in the details of program implementation. There is little hard evidence that more state control would improve efficiency, although it is plausible that making states match the federal benefit expenditures would increase efficiency and reduce payment error. In any case, states could be given substantially more flexibility in running their own programs without eliminating federal standards for basic eligibility and benefit provisions.

CONCLUSION
The Food Stamp Program provides the only universal benefit guarantee for all low-income Americans. As such, it plays a unique role in the current system of means-tested benefits. It also reduces the major welfare disparities among states, and provides protection for the most vulnerable against the hardships inflicted by inflation and unemployment.

In this era of fiscal constraint, the need to examine program reform options for potential cost savings, increased efficiency, and stronger incentives to work is self-evident. And food stamps should be no exception.

As this examination continues and reform options are refined, however, it is important to understand that the size and efficiency of a program bears no necessary relationship to its federal-state structure. It is quite possible for the federal government to maintain responsibility for food stamp eligibility and benefit standards, and to continue to operate food stamps as an entitlement, while still making changes in those standards that would greatly reduce the program's costs.

It is equally possible to give states considerably more flexibility than they now have in food stamp administration. A trend is already underway in this direction through the current federal waiver process.

The danger is that—in the search for cost-effective improvements and budget savings—the current H.R.4 provisions and ongoing welfare reform discussions are neglecting the potential damage to the fundamental integrating mission of the Food Stamp Program.

James Ohls is a senior economist at Mathematica Policy Research.

Related Readings:

"State Response to Welfare Reform: A Race to the Bottom?" by Paul E. Peterson, Welfare Reform Briefs Number 8, Urban Institute, May 1995.

"Rainy Day Funds: Contingency Funding for Block Grants," by Wayne Vroman, Welfare Reform Briefs Number 4, Urban Institute, May 1995.

"The Effects of the House Welfare Bill on Low-Income Families Nationally and By State," Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, May 5, 1995.

1. The asset cutoff is slightly higher for elderly households.

2. Perhaps half of this increased spending on food results from the restricted nature of the benefit. The other half is the normal response to having more income.

3. Paul E. Peterson, "State Response to Welfare Reform: A Race to the Bottom?" Welfare Reform Briefs Number 8, Urban Institute, May 1995.

4. Wayne Vroman, "Rainy Day Funds: Contingency Funding for Welfare Block Grants," Welfare Reform Briefs Number 4, Urban Institute, May 1995.

5. There were a number of changes to the program during this period, but none could account for more than a small part of this increase.

6. If the Food Stamp Program were left untouched and the provisions to turn AFDC into a block grant became law with no maintenance of effort requirement, states would be able to shift costs to the federal government—by cutting AFDC benefits and having one-third of that cut replaced by the food stamp benefit formula.

7. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, "The Effects of the House Welfare Bill on Low-Income Families Nationally and By State," May 5, 1995.
Chapter 14
Reforming the Supplemental Security Income Program for Children
By Pamela Loprest

As part of the federal welfare reform effort, major changes have been proposed for the Supplemental Security Income (SSI) program for children with disabilities. The SSI program provides cash benefits to low-income elderly people and low-income people with disabilities (see Figure 1). The proposed changes to SSI for children would:

restrict eligibility for any benefits by narrowing the disability criteria, and
replace cash benefits with direct services for most of the children who would remain eligible.
Underlying much of the discussion about these proposed reforms are fundamental questions about the purpose of the SSI children's benefit. Should it provide income support for low-income families facing the additional hardships of raising a child with a disability? Or should it focus on meeting the specific disability-related needs of children in these families? Questions of which children should be eligible and whether families should receive cash or services are part of this larger debate.

WHY REFORM SSI?
In 1994, 890,000 children received more than $4 billion in SSI benefits. Although SSI expenditures are less than 10 percent of combined federal, state, and local expenditures on children with disabilities_including Medicaid, special education, and other programs 1—the number of children receiving SSI has more than doubled over the last five years (see Figure 2). Over the same period, adult SSI caseloads increased about 30 percent. The growth is due to many factors, including court cases, changes in administrative rules, and extensive outreach.

"Zebley v. Sullivan."
In 1990, the Supreme Court ruled that SSI did not have disability criteria for children comparable to those of adults, for whom ability to engage in gainful employment is the usual screen. In response, the Social Security Administration (SSA) implemented an Individual Functional Assessment (IFA) process as an additional avenue of eligibility for children. The IFA screens for ability to behave in age-appropriate ways. The General Accounting Office (GAO) found that from 1991 to 1994, about one-third of the children who enrolled in SSI were found to be eligible on the basis of an IFA.

Changes in Eligible Mental Impairments.
In December 1990, SSA began using a revised and expanded list of mental impairments that qualify children for disability assistance. These standards added new mental impairments—such as attention deficit hyperactivity disorder and psychoactive substance dependence disorders—to the list. Awards based on the mental impairment listings almost tripled after these changes, while awards based on physical impairments doubled. 2

Fraud and Abuse?
Concerns have been raised in the press and elsewhere that some children with only mild disabilities are becoming eligible for SSI, that parents may be coaching children to behave in ways that will make them eligible, and that cash benefits are not always spent on disability-related needs or even on the eligible child. 3 Studies conducted by SSA and the Inspector General's office have found little hard evidence of such abuse, although they did identify a number of children receiving benefits who should have been denied eligibility. This problem was attributed, in part, to difficulties in interpreting SSI guidelines, particularly the IFA.

PROPOSED CHANGES IN ELIGIBILITY
Proposed SSI reforms would eliminate use of the IFA for children. Disability determination would rely on the listings of specific impairments for children, which would be reviewed annually for potential revision. All children meeting the impairment listings would remain eligible for Medicaid and for services to be funded by block grants to the states. Eligibility for cash benefits would be tightly restricted (see Figure 3).

These proposed reforms would substantially change the current caseload. Of children currently receiving SSI benefits, 21 percent would continue to be eligible for cash benefits under the new rules. Those whose current eligibility is through the IFA fall into two categories. One group (18 percent of current recipients) would lose all eligibility. The other group includes children with conditions that would probably qualify them through the impairment listings to receive block grant services (8 percent of current recipients). An additional 53 percent who are current recipients through the impairment listings would be eligible only for block grant services under the new rules, but would continue to receive cash benefits under a grandfather clause. Of new applicants who would be eligible for cash benefits under current rules, 21 percent would receive cash benefits, 61 percent would receive block grant services, and 18 percent would be ineligible for any benefits. 4

REPEALING THE IFA
The IFA is a complex, weighted assessment of a child's functioning or abilities in various domains (cognition, social/behavioral skills, communication, motor skills, concen- tration, persistence, and pace). It is targeted for elimination partly because of its complexity and its potential for subjective judgment. Many people agree that the IFA needs improvement to reduce these problems. 5 But some of the complexity reflects the inherent difficulty of measuring disability in children. Children are continually developing and a child's abilities change over time. Also, multiple conditions and impairments combine in ways that can lead to more serious disability than each condition alone.

Many who favor elimination of the IFA assume that—because functional criteria are naturally more subjective—restricting eligibility to medical listings is equivalent to limiting coverage to more serious disabilities. Criteria that are simpler to implement may indeed have the benefit of excluding children with milder disabilities, but they are almost certain to disallow some children with severe disabilities. For example, children who are seriously disabled because of multiple conditions that do not separately meet the severity of the listings may be denied benefits unless some functional assessment is retained.

RESTRICTING CASH BENEFITS
Even prior to SSI's passage in 1972 there was debate over the appropriateness of providing cash payments to children with disabilities. In adult disability programs, cash benefits are viewed as a replacement for earnings of those unable to work. For children, however, the justification for cash benefits continues to be debated. Are they to help meet additional costs associated with the disability, or to replace the earnings of parents who stay home to care for the children?

Additional Costs.
Evidence on the additional costs associated with children's disabilities is limited. While data show that costs associated with a relatively small number of children account for a large percentage of total medical expenditures on children, the extent and nature of the needs of these children beyond medical treatment and other publicly available services (such as special education) are largely unknown. What evidence does exist shows that additional costs vary dramatically with type of disability.

Earnings Replacement.
Reforms calling for payments to children needing personal care assistance respond in part to the concern that parents must take time from work to care for a child with a disability. Indeed, the need for replacement earnings is likely to be great, since so many children on SSI (at least 50 percent) 6 live in single-parent families. But formulating appropriate criteria to determine who would require institutionalization if not given personal assistance is difficult, since the decision to place a child in an institution or residential care facility generally depends on the family situation as well as the specific condition. Like the IFA, this decision is inherently open to subjective judgment by physicians, teachers, and administrators who determine disability.

BLOCK GRANTS FOR SERVICES
The ways in which families use SSI benefits have also come under scrutiny. Current rules require that SSI payments be spent on the needs of the child—food, clothing, shelter, medical care, and personal comfort items. Since all beneficiaries are from low-income families, the greatest immediate needs of these children may well include food and shelter. There is no current requirement for SSI payments to be used to meet disability-related needs. In an effort to restrict benefits to such needs, proposed reforms include block grants to states for direct service provision. These grants would give the states considerable discretion. The services must be targeted to the "unique needs of qualifying children that arise from physical and mental impairments."

In some respects, these services would replace cash benefits for those who do not meet the restrictive criteria for cash but still meet the impairment listings. However, the replacement is not complete. First, states would not be required to serve all children who need a particular service, or offer all services a child may need. And funds to the states would be only 75 percent of current cash benefits. Second, to the extent that cash payments are intended to replace parental earnings (leaving spending choices to the family), services alone do not meet that goal.

More generally, the recent movement toward service provision provides greater assurance that federal funds will be used for the disability-related needs of qualifying children. Other avenues, including voucher systems, may preserve this assurance while still granting a measure of family choice over services. But any new system of noncash benefits is likely to lead to increased administrative costs, particularly since states will need to make their own assessments of children's service needs.

THE FUTURE OF SSI FOR CHILDREN
That children with disabilities in low-income families are disadvantaged is not debated. And there is general agreement that reforms are needed in the SSI program for children, particularly in how eligibility is determined. But the larger issue of the goal of the SSI program remains unresolved, with some arguing that SSI should remain a form of flexible income support for these children. The proposed legislation before Congress would greatly reduce the role of the SSI program in providing such support.

Pamela Loprest is a research associate at the Urban Institute.

Related Readings:

"Findings from the Study of Title XVI Childhood Disability Claims," Office of Supplemental Security Income, Social Security Administration, 1994.

"Concerns About the Participation of Children with Disabilities in the Supplemental Security Income Program," Office of the Inspector General, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 1994.

1. Laudan Aron, Pamela Loprest, and C. Eugene Steuerle, "Systematic Thinking about Government Programs for Children with Disabilities," Urban Institute, March 1995.

2. General Accounting Office, "Social Security: Rapid Rise in Children on SSI Disability Rolls Follows New Regulations," September 1994, HEHS-94-225.

3. For examples, see the Washington Post, February 2, 1994, Wall Street Journal, January 20, 1995, and Baltimore Sun, January 22, 1995.

4. Estimates are from the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services.

5. General Accounting Office, "Social Security: New Functional Assessments for Children Raise Eligibility Questions," March 1995, HEHS-95-66.

6. Office of Supplemental Security Income Policy, Social Security Administration, "Children Receiving SSI," December 1994.

Chapter 15
When Should Immigrants Receive Public Benefits?
by Michael Fix and Wendy Zimmerman

The welfare reform bill that recently passed the House of Representatives (H.R. 1214) would dramatically curb legal immigrants' access to needs-based public benefits. The House bill, part of the Personal Responsibility Act (PRA), bars most legal immigrants from Supplemental Security Income (SSI), Medicaid, and Food Stamps, and from services provided under the Temporary Family Assistance (formerly AFDC) and Social Services block grants. It also requires that the income of an immigrant's sponsor be deemed available to the immigrant for purposes of determining eligibility for all means-tested federal, state, and local programs. This deeming period would last until the immigrant becomes a citizen.

PATTERNS OF WELFARE USE AMONG IMMIGRANTS
Public support for reducing benefits to immigrants is, at least in part, premised on the assumption that welfare use by immigrants is widespread, growing rapidly, and includes those who are here illegally. What are the facts?

First, illegal immigrants are eligible for very few public benefits. The exceptions include emergency medical care, child nutrition, and education. Second, among legal immigrants, it is true that higher proportions of immigrants than of natives use welfare. Closer examination, however, reveals that use is concentrated among two groups - refugees and the elderly (See Figure 1). These two groups represent 40 percent of immigrant welfare users but 21 percent of the immigrant population. 1

Refugees have high welfare use rates partly because they are fleeing persecution, are often physically or psychologically impaired, and typically have no family or job connections. Their special circumstances suggest that their eligibility for and use of benefits should be considered separately from the remainder of the immigrant population.

Welfare use by elderly immigrants is concentrated in the SSI program. Although immigrants make up only 9 percent of the total elderly population, they make up 28 percent of SSI recipients aged 65 and over. Two factors probably account for their high usage. First, many elderly immigrants have not worked enough in the United States to qualify for Social Security. Second, because it is difficult for elderly immigrants to obtain health insurance, many use SSI as a bridge to Medicaid.

For the rest of the immigrant population_non-refugee immigrants of working age - welfare use is about the same as for U.S.-born Americans (about 5 percent), despite the fact that a larger proportion of immigrants than of natives is poor. Sixteen percent of poor immigrants use welfare, compared to 25 percent of poor natives. However, use of welfare by immigrants appears to have risen in recent years, according to an analysis of March 1994 Current Population Survey and 1990 Census data. This rise is probably due in part to the fact that the 2.6 million immigrants who were legalized under the Immigration Reform and Control Act of 1986 (IRCA) have recently become eligible for benefits following a five-year bar. It may also be attributable to rising enrollment of legal immigrants in the SSI disability program.

LIKELY IMPACTS OF REFORM
The immigrant restrictions in the PRA would cut off large numbers of legal immigrants from services, reduce assistance for some citizens, and shift costs to states, localities, and nonprofit organizations.

Some 569,000 AFDC recipients—three-fourths of all foreign-born recipients—would lose benefits as a result of the bar on immigrants. The bar would eliminate benefits for 62,000 families and result in lower benefits for 252,000 families that include citizens, usually children. The PRA also would exclude 520,000, or three-fourths, of immigrant SSI recipients. 2

The U.S. Department of Health and Human Services estimates that some 2.2 million legal immigrants may be denied public assistance.

Restrictions on access to benefits by legal immigrants are expected to produce substantial budgetary savings. The reductions in AFDC benefits alone would save $417 million annually; the SSI restrictions would save $2.3 billion annually.

These cutbacks would have the greatest effect on the handful of states where immigrants are concentrated and on two states in particular - California and New York - where about half of all immigrants live. Because these states have higher immigrant welfare use rates and higher payment levels, they would account for 65 percent of the excluded AFDC recipients and 75 percent of AFDC savings.

The PRA allows state and local governments to deny legal immigrants access to state and locally funded programs and requires them to deem sponsors' income in most means-tested programs. Whether or not states choose to bar immigrants, the six or seven states with the most immigrants will be left with large populations in need. Where no public assistance is available, immigrants would turn to private nonprofit organizations, many of which already face increasing numbers of clients and decreasing funding.

ASSESSMENT OF THE PROPOSALS
Proposals to restrict immigrants' access to services raise a number of troubling issues. First, these proposals appear to have been driven more by an interest in reducing costs than by any coherent set of principles regarding the access of immigrants to public benefits.

Second, an outright bar on eligibility and the requirement for deeming until citizenship would redefine the status of legal immigrants in our society. Historically, we have made few distinctions between legal permanent residents and citizens, and instead have drawn a firm line between legal and undocumented immigrants. Legal immigrants pay taxes and can be drafted in time of war—the main legal obligations of citizens. Restricting access to public benefits until citizenship would remove rights that have traditionally accompanied these responsibilities. Also, making citizenship the gateway to benefits is troubling because it could induce immigrants to naturalize as a means of acquiring or retaining public benefits and not as an expression of their allegiance to the country.

In addition, the proposals restrict immigrants' access to a wide range of public assistance programs, including those designed to protect the public health and the health and safety of children, and those that help immigrants to become self-supporting and better integrated into U.S. society. Finally, on purely administrative grounds, the rush to citizenship likely to result would strain the Immigration and Naturalization Service's already stressed capacity to naturalize immigrants.

PRINCIPLES TO GUIDE REFORM
If current proposals raise so many troubling issues, what types of reforms make sense? We offer four principles to guide discussion. One is the need to prevent an influx of immigrants who become dependent on welfare. A second is the need to promote family—not government—responsibility. For example, adults who bring their elderly parents to this country should assume primary responsibility for their support, at least initially. A third principle is the need to provide a safety net for legal immigrants and their sponsors who fall on hard times and require transitional assistance. A fourth is the need to promote immigrant integration. This suggests making a distinction between programs that provide income assistance and those that provide education, training, or other services that promote mobility.

ALTERNATIVE REFORMS
These principles suggest that the sponsorship and deeming process makes sense, but not for the wide range of programs for which it is required by the PRA.

Sponsorship and Deeming.
Sponsorship and deeming have a strong logic on which reform can build. Under the public charge provision, immigrants can be excluded from the U.S. if they appear likely to become a public charge. One way to overcome this exclusion is to have a sponsor (often a family member) sign a pledge or affidavit of support. The sponsor's income is then deemed to be available to the immigrant for the purpose of qualifying for three means-tested programs: AFDC, SSI, and Food Stamps. These mechanisms allow the nation to admit immigrants who may be poor at the time of entry but who have the potential to become tax-paying contributors to the economy.

Under the current system, however, the affidavit of support signed by a sponsor is not legally enforceable. Thus, a sponsor may refuse to provide for an immigrant he or she has sponsored even though the sponsor's income continues to be deemed to the immigrant, usually making the immigrant ineligible for benefits.

Making the Affidavit of Support Enforceable.
This problem could be addressed by making the affidavit of support legally enforceable. If the deeming requirements were waived when a sponsor abandons the immigrant, the immigrant would then have access to a safety net and the state could recoup the funds from the sponsor. Such a policy would serve three purposes: it would discipline sponsors, protect immigrants, and safeguard taxpayers. The PRA makes the affidavit of support enforceable by the government but does not require states to pay benefits in cases where sponsors renege on their commitments.

Also, the current sponsorship system is flawed in that there is no reliable way to determine whether an immigrant has a sponsor. Many eligibility workers now simply ask the immigrant whether he or she is sponsored. One possible long-term solution is to include a code signifying sponsorship on immigrants' documentation.

How Long Should Deeming Last?
If sponsorship and deeming make sense, but deeming until citizenship does not, how long should deeming last? Should it last three years, as is currently the case for AFDC and Food Stamps? Five years, as is currently the case for SSI? Or some longer, finite period?

One strategy might be to have a uniform five-year deeming period for the programs in which deeming is appropriate. Five years is the period during which an immigrant can be deported for becoming a public charge, the period that most immigrants must wait to apply for citizenship, and the period for which immigrants legalizing under IRCA were barred from benefits. A five-year deeming period would help accomplish the goals of family responsibility and encouraging integration by temporarily restricting access to welfare, while at the same time limiting both the burden imposed on the immigrant and the liability of the sponsor.

Focus on Refugees and the Elderly. In addition to improving the current system of deeming and sponsorship, reforms might also focus on the two groups with the highest rates of welfare use - refugees and the elderly. Since refugees are concentrated most heavily in California and New York, and since welfare use rates are higher there, focusing on the state-run refugee resettlement programs in those states may go a long way toward alleviating refugee welfare dependency.

As many elderly immigrants appear to use SSI to obtain Medicaid, their use may decrease if access to health insurance is expanded. One approach would be to compel the immigrants or their sponsors to buy into Medicare.

Michael Fix is director of the Urban Institute's Immigrant Policy Program. Wendy Zimmermann is a research assocate at the Urban Institute. This research was funded by the Andrew W. Mellon Foundation.

Related Readings:

"After Arrival: An Overview of Federal Immigrant Policy in the United States," by Michael Fix and Wendy Zimmermann, Urban Institute, July 1993.

"Immigration and Immigrants: Setting the Record Straight," by Michael Fix, Jeffrey Passel, Mara Enchautegui, and Wendy Zimmermann, Urban Institute Press, May 1994.

"Citizens, Aliens, Membership, and the Constitution," by Alexander Aleinikoff, in "Constitutional Commentary," vol. 7, 1990, pp.9-34.

"The American Kaleidoscope: Race, Ethnicity, and the Civic Culture," by Lawrence Fuchs, Wesleyan University Press, 1990.

1. Data on welfare use are from the March 1994 Current Population Survey (CPS) and refer to self-reported use of AFDC, SSI, or General Assistance. Specific references to SSI are based on data from the Social Security Administration.

2. Impact estimates for AFDC are based on the Urban Institute's AFDC-QC model, using 1993 AFDC Quality Control data. Impact estimates for SSI are based on Congressional Budget Office analysis.
http://www.urban.org/publications/306620.html


I really hopes this helps. I know its long, but I thought It would save you time if you didnt have the time to look it all up on your own.

2006-10-11 06:36:53 · answer #1 · answered by Shalamar Rue 4 · 1 1

1

2016-12-24 20:01:42 · answer #2 · answered by Anonymous · 0 0

2

2017-01-19 21:44:31 · answer #3 · answered by ? 3 · 0 0

HAVE YOU GOT 3 OR 4 HOURS TO SPARE

2006-10-11 05:18:50 · answer #4 · answered by bri hawk 2 · 1 1

Everyone is in need of some additional money in the free time and to say your mind and earn money is a really simple job, you sign up with an email, verify the email, receive emails for taking surveys, make the study and make money-- much simpler cannot be.
Look here https://tr.im/6lAU4 , you will earn money to state you mind.
Your opinion matters so be carefully offering answers to research study studies, you are personally assisting to form the business strategies of executives worldwide.
The studies in this website are selected to assist you make money for your time. Each survey has a cash value for successful completion and honest responses. Take some time from your day to help make the world a much better place- and get paid for this.

2016-05-15 17:50:29 · answer #5 · answered by viola 2 · 0 0

A common misconception is that you will have to be a financial and business expert in order to successfully trade binary options. However, this is not true at all. Learn here https://tr.im/AxVbn

Perhaps it’s true when it comes to traditional stocks trading but definitely not true in the case of binaries. You don’t have to be an expert to predict the movement of certain assets.

2016-05-01 09:26:06 · answer #6 · answered by ? 3 · 0 0

6

2017-02-27 21:52:43 · answer #7 · answered by William 3 · 0 0

4

2017-02-17 13:51:21 · answer #8 · answered by Ashley 4 · 0 0

3

2017-02-16 21:47:43 · answer #9 · answered by matthews 4 · 0 0

Naturally Increase Penis Size : http://LongPenis.uzaev.com/?qnpz

2016-06-26 21:36:35 · answer #10 · answered by ? 3 · 0 0

Put upward more Christmas lights.

2016-06-23 02:38:44 · answer #11 · answered by Anonymous · 0 0

fedest.com, questions and answers